State Capitalism In Eurasia
eBook - ePub

State Capitalism In Eurasia

Martin C Spechler, Joachim Ahrens;Herman W Hoen;;

  1. 156 páginas
  2. English
  3. ePUB (apto para móviles)
  4. Disponible en iOS y Android
eBook - ePub

State Capitalism In Eurasia

Martin C Spechler, Joachim Ahrens;Herman W Hoen;;

Detalles del libro
Vista previa del libro
Índice
Citas

Información del libro

This is the first book to specify the type of economic system that has arisen in Central Asia, replacing the simplistic ideas of "petro-state" or "resource dependent."

The book presents three types of state capitalism now established in the former Soviet Union states of Eurasia — crony, dual-sector, and predatory capitalism. It provides first-hand research based on extensive interviewing in the native languages in five of the six. From the political economic perspective, it surveys the source of resources for these authoritarian regimes, their decision-making, and the disposition of government funds, including corruption.

Contents:

  • Definition of "State Capitalism" and "Dual Economy" in the Current Authoritarian Systems of the Russian Federation, Uzbekistan, Kazakhstan, Kyrgyzstan, Tajikistan, and Turkmenistan
  • Comparative Evaluation of Their Merit Performance Based on Internationally Published Statistics about Their Efficiency, Growth, Equity, and Stability


Readership: Academics, professionals, policy-makers, graduate and undergraduate students interested in economic development of Eurasia.Russia;Uzbekistan;Kazakhstan;Tajikistan;Dual Economy;Cronyism;Predatory0

Preguntas frecuentes

¿Cómo cancelo mi suscripción?
Simplemente, dirígete a la sección ajustes de la cuenta y haz clic en «Cancelar suscripción». Así de sencillo. Después de cancelar tu suscripción, esta permanecerá activa el tiempo restante que hayas pagado. Obtén más información aquí.
¿Cómo descargo los libros?
Por el momento, todos nuestros libros ePub adaptables a dispositivos móviles se pueden descargar a través de la aplicación. La mayor parte de nuestros PDF también se puede descargar y ya estamos trabajando para que el resto también sea descargable. Obtén más información aquí.
¿En qué se diferencian los planes de precios?
Ambos planes te permiten acceder por completo a la biblioteca y a todas las funciones de Perlego. Las únicas diferencias son el precio y el período de suscripción: con el plan anual ahorrarás en torno a un 30 % en comparación con 12 meses de un plan mensual.
¿Qué es Perlego?
Somos un servicio de suscripción de libros de texto en línea que te permite acceder a toda una biblioteca en línea por menos de lo que cuesta un libro al mes. Con más de un millón de libros sobre más de 1000 categorías, ¡tenemos todo lo que necesitas! Obtén más información aquí.
¿Perlego ofrece la función de texto a voz?
Busca el símbolo de lectura en voz alta en tu próximo libro para ver si puedes escucharlo. La herramienta de lectura en voz alta lee el texto en voz alta por ti, resaltando el texto a medida que se lee. Puedes pausarla, acelerarla y ralentizarla. Obtén más información aquí.
¿Es State Capitalism In Eurasia un PDF/ePUB en línea?
Sí, puedes acceder a State Capitalism In Eurasia de Martin C Spechler, Joachim Ahrens;Herman W Hoen;; en formato PDF o ePUB, así como a otros libros populares de Economia y Economia politica. Tenemos más de un millón de libros disponibles en nuestro catálogo para que explores.

Información

Editorial
WSPC
Año
2017
ISBN
9789813149397
Categoría
Economia

Chapter 1

Defining State-Capitalism

After the collapse of communism and the demise of the Soviet Union, transformation strategies for post-socialist countries were dominated by the liberal school of economic thought (e.g., Åslund, 2013). In an attempt to create a full-fledged market economy embedded in a democratic order, all the countries needed to stabilize, liberalize, and privatize their economies. In whatever timing and sequencing strategy — a controversy that was dominating the so-called shock-versus-gradualism debate — the ideas on the role of the state were clear. It needed to retreat from an active direction of the economy! A third way in which both the market and the state were to coincide was deemed obsolete.
Twenty five years of transformation experiences have shown that the landscape of emerging economic systems is quite diverse. Different policies of stabilization have been applied, as has been the case with liberalization and privatization strategies. More importantly, a revival of the role for the state has also occurred. Some have indicated that the ruble crisis in 1998 triggered opposition to the politics of marketization and the neo-liberal discourse of radical reform (Bönker, Müller and Pickel, 2002), but this opposition more or less remained within the margins of timing and sequencing of reforms. The idea of a small state remained more or less undisputed. The diverging responses to the global financial crisis in 2008/2009, however, did lead to new perspectives on the role of the state. Scholars frequently indicated that those economies, which have relied on a larger role of the state, have been more successful in addressing the social and economic consequences of the crisis. Thus, many commentators, politicians, and academics have welcomed the return of the economically active state (Kurlantzick, 2016).
This book addresses politico-economic developments in Central Asia — Kazakhstan, Kyrgyzstan, Tajikistan, Turkmenistan, Uzbekistan, and also Russia — and it particularly focuses on the economic role of the state since the beginning of the transition processes in the early 1990s. Relative to Eastern European countries and other successor states of the Soviet Union, the Central Asian countries have relied more heavily on the state.1 Even more so, given the extraordinary achievements of China as a state-capitalist country, we consider it reasonable to investigate state-capitalism as an emerging politico-economic order in Central Asia. Therefore, this study will not solely examine policies of stabilization, liberalization, and privatization, but also focus on politico-economic institutions that set the rules of the game (North, 1990).
In this book, we will define state-capitalism as official ownership and management of significant means of production, including any new enterprises introduced. The state may, e.g., control strategic industries and stock resources to assure national defense or only own minority shares in other important industries. The government appoints management personnel and decides the use of gross profits for new investments. The usual purposes of such control are to promote growth and equitable distribution and to offset market failures or externalities, such as pollution. The obvious contrast to state-capitalism is free market capitalism, where economic decisions are made by private individuals based on prices prevailing in their market environment. Bolsheviks such as Vladimir Lenin and Nikolai Bukharin had insisted that worker interests in state-capitalism would be represented in the “dictatorship of the proletariat,” that is, in practice the Communist Party. In contrast to Soviet socialism, state-capitalism is not controlled by the working class, who earn wages, and any private owners have no obligation to social welfare.

Three Kinds of State-Capitalism

In the previous literature, the label state-capitalism has often been used for political and ideological purposes. Indeed, the expression originated in the debates within socialist circles at the late nineteenth century (Carver, 2011, p. 399). It is believed that the German socialist Wilhelm Liebknecht coined the term in 1896 by stating: “Nobody has combated State Socialism more than we German Socialists; nobody has shown more distinctively than I that State Socialism is really State-Capitalism” (Liebknecht, 1896, p. 4). Thus, these socialists were criticizing any economy that would exploit the workers in the interests of the state rather than private owners. Later on, however, some socialists perceived state socialism as an effective and efficient alternative to capitalism from finance capitalism, associated with monopolistic control by money interests.
With the retreat of communism at the end of the 1980s and the beginning of the 1990s, the term state-capitalism lost its currency along with real or state socialism, both terms associated with the USSR. Francis Fukuyama (1992, p. xi) expressed the idea that the end of the 1980s was “not just the end of the cold war, or the passing of a particular period of post-war history, but the end of history as such: that is, the end point of mankind’s ideological evolution and the universalization of Western liberal democracy as the final form of human government.” To him, the spread of successful liberal market economies throughout much of the globe appeared to render further discussion of alternative economic orders superfluous.
But the global financial crisis of 2008/2009, slower growth in Western Europe and elsewhere, as contrasted with consistently fast and dynamic growth in China and Southeast Asia, revived state-capitalism as an attractive alternative (Bremmer, 2009). “The era of free-market triumphalism has come to a shuddering half, and the crisis that destroyed Lehman Brothers in 2008 is now engulfing much of the rich world” (The Economist, 2012). Thus, state-capitalism has increasingly become attractive as an alternative development model for catching-up economies.
The new literature on state-capitalism identifies different categories. Kurlantzick (2016), for example, distinguishes between “autocratic” and “democratic” as well as between “efficient” versus “inefficient” state-capitalist regimes. He identifies countries from China to Russia, from Brazil to Saudi Arabia, and from India to Singapore and eventually Norway as state-capitalist. We neglect this classification as too vague and possibly misleading because virtually all emerging markets as well as resource-rich advanced economies may qualify as state-capitalist despite significant differences regarding the role of government in their economies.
Bremmer (2010, p. 23) points out that state-capitalism “dominates markets primarily for political gain,” and he adds that “most important [tools of state-capitalism; the authors] are national oil (and gas) corporations (NOCs), other state-owned enterprises (SOEs), privately owned national champions, and sovereign wealth funds (SWFs)” (Bremmer, 2010, p. 54). Refraining from day-to-day control, governments use direct and more subtle indirect tools, institutions, and measures to manage strategic sectors of the economy. They also take advantage of capitalist institutions such as stock markets and embrace globalization as long as it serves vested politico-economic interests.
Following this line of reasoning and given the fact that all countries under scrutiny in this book are non-democratic and can barely be called efficient, we identify three different types of state-capitalism in today’s Eurasia: crony or bureaucratic capitalism in Russia and Kyrgyzstan, dual-economy capitalism in Kazakhstan and Uzbekistan, and what we will call predatory capitalism in Tajikistan and Turkmenistan. Although all six are authoritarian regimes with only the formalities of democracy — such as elections or parliaments — we wish to distinguish three ideal types (referring to Max Weber’s “Gedankenbilder,” i.e., mental images) to emphasize the main character of their practice and prospects.2 The two crony or kleptocratic forms of state-capitalism began as failed market regimes. Dual-economy state-capitalism has a recognized and growing periphery of market-based businesses besides strategic sectors that support the regime. The last two regimes are essentially one-man autocracies that take their support from two main sources: taxes on the subsistence sector and international loans, remittances, or humanitarian aid. Decisions are made by the head man and his close associates, a kind of political household.

Modern-Day State-Capitalism

But what kind of politico-economic order is meant by today’s “state-capitalism”? The Economist’s survey in 2012 contrasted this new form with old state-capitalism, in which the state owns and plans most of the means of production in industry, natural resources, and foreign trade. This was true of Nazi Germany and Soviet Russia, where autarky was long preferred for fear of outside exploitation (Holzman, 1987, pp. 91–109). In the Soviet Union small private plots, professional services — to the extent that they had been allowed — suffered from supply constraints (Kornai, 1980), leading to a large shadow economy. These 20th century forms did indeed embrace science in technology and management, offered free health care and education, and tolerated small businesses with limits. Besides these common policies, however, new state-capitalism is supposed to “meld the powers of the state with the powers of capitalism” (Wooldridge, 2012, p. 3). As practiced in East and Southeast Asia these days, state-capitalism may embrace globalization, open trade, and funding from international financial organizations and even listing (usually minority) shares on the stock exchanges of the world. All these practices were opposed by Soviet practice and ideology under Lenin, Josef Stalin, and their successors. The older state-capitalism did not allow investors to pick winners and losers for investing or allow its currency to fluctuate or permit off-shoring and tax avoidance. It did not make indelible commitments to multinational corporations or international banks. The newer state-capitalism of the end of the 20th century does all these things.
Following the wartime break in their national histories, semi-authoritarian governments in post-war Japan, Park Chung Hee’s South Korea, and Lee Kwan Yew’s Singapore successfully adopted state-capitalism with Asian values. They created national champions, chaebols, or strategic industries. Those creations still exist in various new forms. They include huge state-owned companies like Japan Post Holdings, Daewoo, and Singapore Airlines. In some semi-authoritarian Asian countries with state-capitalism, officials interfere in business in ways quite distinct from the organization and behavior of the Soviet command economy (Lavigne, 1999, pp. 10–15). But planning and control are non-mandatory or looser. The central state refrains from decreeing orders regarding what, how much and for whom to produce. Parliamentary parties or other political actors exercise their role in deciding how profits are to be used. Of course, liberal capitalist countries like the USA and European states also headquarter huge multinational companies — Exxon Mobil, Unilever, and Norway’s Statoil and Statkraft — but their parliamentary regimes do not dominate the companies’ decision-making. By contrast, in the People’s Republic of China, such companies, which account for 80 percent of the capitalization on the country’s stock exchange, are ultimately controlled by the Chinese Communist Party. In authoritarian versions of state-capitalism, such as China and countries of the Persian Gulf, politicians have more power than they would have in semi-authoritarian or liberal market economies. In these authoritarian regimes, the state-capitalist system primarily serves the interest of the elites (Bremmer, 2009, p. 52). Managers and their policies often need to be approved by the ruling political parties or state holding companies. Along with this direct interference, the state may be willing to provide or guarantee cheap loans, favorable prices, or assured demand. If successfully managed, state-capitalist regimes can be politically stable if they gain legitimacy through comparatively high economic growth rates, success in international relations, and the provision of public goods to maintain acceptable social standards. Up to now, this has been the case in Russia, Kazakhstan, and Uzbekistan.3
In contrast to the former Soviet bloc, many of today’s best performing state-owned companies are globally competitive. Many are oil or natural-gas companies selling in a worldwide market. Russia’s Gazprom, e.g., is a dominant provider of Europe’s natural gas. But state-owned companies also operate in the field of consumer goods such as mobile phones. New state-capitalism does not necessarily exclude private enterprises. In semi-authoritarian states, significant numbers of private enterprises coexist very well with the flourishing state-dominated sector. In today’s Russia, the agricultural sector is market-oriented with little interference; it exports grain and imports many vegetable and fruit products from abroad. In China, private and even foreign firms may benefit from intercourse with booming state-owned companies, as well as corrupt local officials.

Shortcomings of State-Capitalism

Despite the fact that state-capitalism has been praised for its economic success, it is important to emphasize the drawbacks that may impede the sustainability of the system. From the point of view of material advance, state-capitalism has been successful in catching up with the most developed parts of the world. Hence, state-driven growth is often found in transition economies and in less developed countries, but it usually fails in nurturing innovation, as we shall see (The Economist, 2012, pp. 9–10). Kurlantzick (2016) points out that modern state-capitalism can, however, be very competitive and is able to compete with private multinationals. For Central Asia, however, we question this argument, because this hybrid economic order is vulnerable to rent seeking, corruption and cronyism (Åslund, 2007, pp. 47–53). This hinders private-sector creativity and individual initiative. In addition, such a regime discriminates against the non-privileged sectors of the economy and thereby possibly increases income and asset disparities. From a political point of view, there is doubt whether a population currently experiencing increasing prosperity will be willing indefinitely to accept benefits flowing disproportionately to small political elites (Bremmer, 2009, p. 53). Hence, one may expect growing acceptance issues in the population which might imply political instabilities in the course of time, especially if a state-capitalist regime lacks public capacities to implement policies effectively.

What is Dual-Economy Capitalism?

In a dual-economy form of state-capitalism, which we explore here in the cases of Kazakhstan and Uzbekistan, there is a state-driven, modern and export-oriented core sector, which coexists with a smaller, usually less advanced private sector. The term dual economy was coined by Julius Herman Boeke (1953), a Dutch academic and civil servant who applied the term to the Dutch-Indies, an economy and a society then divided between the traditional hinterland and the modern sectors in which the Dutch colonial capitalists operated.4 As later discovered, the concept of a dual-economy applied well to production and business structures that existed in a number of developing countries. Almost all were characterized by their asymmetry and rigidity into two separate and distinct sectors within one country.
Previous models of the dual economy posited an advanced manufacturing sector organized oriented to the world market, along with a deprived rural sector relying on the traditional methods of production and distribution. The most famous early example of a dual-economy approach came from W. Arthur Lewis and his followers, Fei and Ranis (1964). Lewis theorized that “capitalist” sectors of poor countries could draw on unlimited supplies of labor from the “backward” non-capitalist or “subsistence” sectors (Lewis, 1954). These countries were typically overpopulated, he thought, so the incremental contribution of agricultural labor approached zero. Therefore, surplus labor could be released to urban industries without reducing agricultural output. While in standard economic theory, earnings are determined by the value of a worker’s marginal productivity (Gylfason, 1999, pp. 26–28), in the Lewis’ model, rural laborers receive customary subsistence derived from average productivity of the group or village. The salience of group or village interests is one feature of many primitive or backward societies, alone with strong religious or magical beliefs. Indeed, average incomes in rural areas would eventually rise owing to gradual emigration of low-productivity members to the cities or abroad, while industrial wages would remain stable, allowing profits for new investments. The idea of conventional consumption norms divorced from marginal productivity in village agriculture was radically different from neoclassical models thought to characterize all sectors, even of poor countries. The Lewis model would, however, be of little use to present-day understanding of most Eurasian economies. Their inhabitants’ adoption of material values and more individualism make it more reasonable to assume rational (i.e., material utility maximizing) behavior in all parts of post-Soviet society. For the purposes of applying a dual-economy approach to state-capitalist Central Asian countries, according to our observations, one would also have to modify the notion of backwardness because most union republics of the USSR, including Uzbekistan and Kazakhstan, had experienced considerable urbanization, secularization, and industrialization (Nove and Newth, 1967). In Kyrgyzstan, Tajikistan, and Turkmenistan, urbanized capital districts are also clearly most affected by secular motivations.
In dual-economy types of state-capitalism, according to our approach, emphasis is on how different organizational structures may suit the conditions of each sector. In state-capitalist countries, the peripheral firms may be petty capitalist, though often using modern technology, but are regulated by local market forces. Strong competition and prices, rather than personal ties, become the key coordination mechanisms and incentives. In the core, on the other hand, patronage and political advantage are the common motivation. Though set by the state, the structures, regulations, and interventions regarding both core and periphery must suit the interests of elites without compromising the intere...

Índice

  1. Cover
  2. Halftitle
  3. Title
  4. Copyright
  5. About the Authors
  6. Acknowledgement
  7. Contents
  8. Chapter 1 Defining State-Capitalism
  9. Chapter 2 Russia: Crony Capitalism, Putin-Style
  10. Chapter 3 Kyrgyzstan: Sad Poster-Child of Neo-liberalism
  11. Chapter 4 Kazakhstan: A Dual Economy with Developmental Characteristics
  12. Chapter 5 Uzbekistan: Economic Life Under Control and Beyond Control
  13. Chapter 6 Tajikistan and Turkmenistan: Predatory State-Capitalism
  14. Chapter 7 Conclusion
  15. References
  16. Index
Estilos de citas para State Capitalism In Eurasia

APA 6 Citation

Spechler, M., & Hoen;;, J. A. (2017). State Capitalism In Eurasia ([edition unavailable]). World Scientific Publishing Company. Retrieved from https://www.perlego.com/book/853547/state-capitalism-in-eurasia-pdf (Original work published 2017)

Chicago Citation

Spechler, Martin, and Joachim Ahrens;Herman Hoen;; (2017) 2017. State Capitalism In Eurasia. [Edition unavailable]. World Scientific Publishing Company. https://www.perlego.com/book/853547/state-capitalism-in-eurasia-pdf.

Harvard Citation

Spechler, M. and Hoen;;, J. A. (2017) State Capitalism In Eurasia. [edition unavailable]. World Scientific Publishing Company. Available at: https://www.perlego.com/book/853547/state-capitalism-in-eurasia-pdf (Accessed: 14 October 2022).

MLA 7 Citation

Spechler, Martin, and Joachim Ahrens;Herman Hoen;; State Capitalism In Eurasia. [edition unavailable]. World Scientific Publishing Company, 2017. Web. 14 Oct. 2022.