Markets for Managers
eBook - ePub

Markets for Managers

A Managerial Economics Primer

Anthony J. Evans

Share book
  1. English
  2. ePUB (mobile friendly)
  3. Available on iOS & Android
eBook - ePub

Markets for Managers

A Managerial Economics Primer

Anthony J. Evans

Book details
Book preview
Table of contents
Citations

About This Book

An accessible text that provides managers with a well-rounded economic awareness

Successful managers possess an understanding of economic and market principles as they relate to business itself. Markets for Managers presents managerial economics in a casual, accessible format that will help management professionals take economic realities into account when running their companies or divisions. The book takes a global perspective while covering the full range of micro- and macroeconomic principles that managers around the world need to know. Complete with online resources that include further reading and a YouTube playlist, this guide puts business management practice within its economic context to produce a practical tool for managers.

By understanding market operation and what might cause market failure, management professionals can lead companies that respond to market pressures and align operating strategies with economic realities. Monetary and fiscal policies affect businesses of all sizes, and in Markets for Managers, business leaders can learn how to read the ever-shifting fiscal landscape.

  • Delivers market information tailored to managers and the managerial decision-making process
  • Comprehensively explains macro- and microeconomic ideas in language that's accessible
  • Provides concrete suggestions for utilizing market knowledge to improve internal operations and align incentives
  • Helps managers build a global view of business for optimal decision making

The practical format of Markets for Managers is perfect for professionals and students who want to gain an applied perspective on today's most pressing economic issues.

Frequently asked questions

How do I cancel my subscription?
Simply head over to the account section in settings and click on “Cancel Subscription” - it’s as simple as that. After you cancel, your membership will stay active for the remainder of the time you’ve paid for. Learn more here.
Can/how do I download books?
At the moment all of our mobile-responsive ePub books are available to download via the app. Most of our PDFs are also available to download and we're working on making the final remaining ones downloadable now. Learn more here.
What is the difference between the pricing plans?
Both plans give you full access to the library and all of Perlego’s features. The only differences are the price and subscription period: With the annual plan you’ll save around 30% compared to 12 months on the monthly plan.
What is Perlego?
We are an online textbook subscription service, where you can get access to an entire online library for less than the price of a single book per month. With over 1 million books across 1000+ topics, we’ve got you covered! Learn more here.
Do you support text-to-speech?
Look out for the read-aloud symbol on your next book to see if you can listen to it. The read-aloud tool reads text aloud for you, highlighting the text as it is being read. You can pause it, speed it up and slow it down. Learn more here.
Is Markets for Managers an online PDF/ePUB?
Yes, you can access Markets for Managers by Anthony J. Evans in PDF and/or ePUB format, as well as other popular books in Business & Finanza. We have over one million books available in our catalogue for you to explore.

Information

Publisher
Wiley
Year
2014
ISBN
9781118867952
Edition
1
Subtopic
Finanza

CHAPTER 1
Incentives Matter

‘The theory of economics does not furnish a body of settled conclusions immediately applicable in policy. It is a method rather than a doctrine, an apparatus of mind, a technique of thinking which helps its possessor to draw correct conclusions.’
—John Maynard Keynes1
In early 1998, day care centres around Haifa, in Israel, had a problem. It was a problem common to many of us who have looked after children for a living: late parents.2 After a long day being responsible for other people's children, by 4pm the teachers were ready to go home. And they weren't being paid for staying any longer. But invariably some parents would be late, and someone would have to stay behind and wait with the child. But one day some social scientists turned up (or rather, sent their research assistants) and made a suggestion: why not fine the parents for being late? It is a solution any economist would give.
Over the next few weeks things carried on as normal, as the researchers gathered data before making any changes. Then, they adopted a policy where any parent who was more than 10 minutes late would pay a $3 fine. But instead of reducing lateness, the number of late pickups more than doubled. The incentive backfired.
As an economist, I've heard this example a lot. It's often used to show economists that assuming people's behaviour can be manipulated with financial incentives is naïve and narrow minded. Indeed there is some truth to this. Just because originally there was no fine doesn't mean that there was no incentive to be on time. The social norm is to be on time, and late parents probably felt guilty. Once the arrangement moved from the social to a financial realm, parents realised they could ‘buy’ the right to be late. Indeed they weren't just buying the right to be late, but also the ability to not feel guilty about it. In fact, maybe the lesson of the day care experiment is not that economists overstate their subject matter, but that non-economists understate it. After all, the average monthly cost was about $380. A good economist would suggest that the fine was set at a price that was too low! If the goal was to reduce lateness, raise the fine. And even more importantly, discovering the point at which the fine has an effect will help the day care centre to know just how valuable the parents consider their time to be. This whole experiment might help them to discover which opening hours best suit their customers. Clearly the parents are willing to pay the teachers to stay later. Far from demonstrating the failure of markets, this example is like a cursory foray into their magic.
We tend to think that economics is the study of the economy, and indeed this is an important application. But economics isn't a subject matter; it's a way of thinking. The essence of the economic way of thinking is to understand how incentives and institutions affect people's behaviour. In terms of management, economics can give us important clues about why behaviour may be generating bad outcomes. Understanding concepts such as opportunity cost, price elasticity and price discrimination are tools that managers can use to improve a company's performance. But economics does more than this. It provides us with a way of thinking about human action. Economics is the study of society, and the tools with which we understand social behaviour are of direct relevance to management.

1.1 MANAGERIAL INDIVIDUALISM

In their excellent textbook Managerial Economics, Luke Froeb and Brian McCann offer the following guide to decision making: when you see an outcome that you deem to be undesirable, ask yourself three questions:3
  1. Who made the bad decision?
  2. Did they have the information they needed?
  3. Did they have the right incentives?
All too often the first question isn't even asked, and failure is put down to some collective problem that is ill defined and impossible to alter. The main insight of managerial economics is to focus on the information and incentive mechanisms that help guide decision making. If you do not even know who is making the bad decision, there's little hope of finding out why they did so. This book intends to explore the information channels and incentive mechanisms that create value. It will focus on how markets can be utilised to help solve these problems.
The reason why economists make individual choice the centre of analysis is because we posit that only individuals choose.4 This is not the same thing as saying that only individuals matter, or that ‘society’ is nothing more than a group of individuals. It stems from a concept called ‘methodological individualism’, which Jon Elster defines as ‘the doctrine that all social phenomena (their structure and their change) are in principle explicable only in terms of individuals – their properties, goals and beliefs’.5 We can talk about how ‘Heinz have decided to build a new factory’ but according to methodological individualism the literal interpretation that the company itself made the decision is false. Families, businesses and nations might have common interests and work together to achieve shared goals, but it is only as individuals that we make decisions. This doesn't imply that social phenomena aren't important. On the contrary, it is precisely because we wish to understand social phenomena that we see it through the lens of individual choice. We need to understand the preferences and constraints of individual members, to see how collective decisions get made, because social entities are the result of individual action.
This is why the first question – identifying the decision maker – is so important. It is only then that we can look into the circumstances in which the decision was made and what their objectives were. Economics helps to reveal the information and incentive systems within which we operate. The crucial point is that although these institutions influence our choices, we also have choices about how to shape them. In short there's a feedback mechanism between individuals and institutions, but with us in the driving seat. Institutions are, as John Commons defines them, ‘collective action in control, liberation and expansion of individual action’.6
In this book we will make two key behavioural assumptions:
  1. The rationality assumption – incentives affect behaviour (at the margin)
    The idea that incentives matter seems obvious but is often counterintuitive. My brother-in-law enjoys adventure and on a recent skiing trip realised that he was travelling faster than 30mph. My parents were worried that he might hurt himself if he crashed, so they bought him a helmet. Guess what? The next day he promptly reached 58mph! All safety equipment has a curious potential to backfire, because it alters your incentives to take risks. Although helmets mean that you are less likely to be injured if you have an accident, they also affect the probability of having an accident in the first place. In the case of skiing a helmet reduces the cost of an accident. All else being equal, this makes you more willing to risk having one. This may not be a large effect, and perhaps if you wore a helmet you'd think that you'd be just as careful as without. But the helmet is incentivising you to be more reckless, not less. Not only this, but it can affect other people's behaviour. If you wear a helmet you also reduce the cost to other people of them crashing into you. At the margin, it could lead to more accidents.7
    Think of the difference between Rugby and American Football. Both are similar sports but one key difference is that the players of the latter wear helmets. Which one do you think has the most neck and spinal injuries? The obvious answer would be Rugby, because they don't wear hard protection.8 But because of this they face a higher cost of putting their head into a dangerous situation. Maybe they are less likely to enter tackles headfirst? Indeed not only do American Footballers face a higher rate of neck and head injuries, there are calls by some to ban helmets for this very reason.9 A 2013 book on the subject claimed that in 1999 the NFL paid compensation to retired players after accepting they had suffered brain damage.10 Since the year 2000 neurosurgeons have been warning the league that the sport was causing depression, dementia and brain damage.11
  2. The self-interest assumption – people pursue their own self-interest
    Again, to economists this assumption is self-evident and trivial. Maybe we don't really know what other people's interests are. Either way, we put our own interests ahead of the interests of others. This does not imply that we are narrowly selfish. It doesn't mean that we're motivated by material possessions, or monetary gains. The welfare of your children, or colleagues, may be your primary goal. Your self-interest may well be altruistic. But it's what drives your economic decision making. As Gary Becker said,
    I have tried to pry economists away from narrow assumptions about self-interest. Behaviour is driven by a much richer set of values and preferences. Individuals maximise welfare as they conceive it, whether they be selfish, altruistic, loyal, spiteful, or masochistic.12
The implications of these assumptions are crucial to management. Forget trying to ‘motivate’ people. Forget about coaching. The goal of management is really quite simple – to change behaviour you need to change what is in people's self-interest to pursue. You need to change incentives. Achieving that goal is wher...

Table of contents