Information Economics
eBook - ePub

Information Economics

Urs Birchler, Monika Bütler

Share book
  1. 464 pages
  2. English
  3. ePUB (mobile friendly)
  4. Available on iOS & Android
eBook - ePub

Information Economics

Urs Birchler, Monika Bütler

Book details
Book preview
Table of contents
Citations

About This Book

This new text book by Urs Birchler and Monika Butler is an introduction to the study of how information affects economic relations. The authors provide a narrative treatment of the more formal concepts of Information Economics, using easy to understand and lively illustrations from film and literature and nutshell examples. The book first covers the economics of information in a 'man versus nature' context, explaining basic concepts like rational updating or the value of information. Then in a 'man versus man' setting, Birchler and Butler describe strategic issues in the use of information: the make-buy-or-copy decision, the working and failure of markets and the important role of outguessing each other in a macroeconomic context. It closes with a 'man versus himself' perspective, focusing on information management within the individual.

This book also comes with a supporting website (www.alicebob.info), maintained by the authors.

Frequently asked questions

How do I cancel my subscription?
Simply head over to the account section in settings and click on “Cancel Subscription” - it’s as simple as that. After you cancel, your membership will stay active for the remainder of the time you’ve paid for. Learn more here.
Can/how do I download books?
At the moment all of our mobile-responsive ePub books are available to download via the app. Most of our PDFs are also available to download and we're working on making the final remaining ones downloadable now. Learn more here.
What is the difference between the pricing plans?
Both plans give you full access to the library and all of Perlego’s features. The only differences are the price and subscription period: With the annual plan you’ll save around 30% compared to 12 months on the monthly plan.
What is Perlego?
We are an online textbook subscription service, where you can get access to an entire online library for less than the price of a single book per month. With over 1 million books across 1000+ topics, we’ve got you covered! Learn more here.
Do you support text-to-speech?
Look out for the read-aloud symbol on your next book to see if you can listen to it. The read-aloud tool reads text aloud for you, highlighting the text as it is being read. You can pause it, speed it up and slow it down. Learn more here.
Is Information Economics an online PDF/ePUB?
Yes, you can access Information Economics by Urs Birchler, Monika Bütler in PDF and/or ePUB format, as well as other popular books in Business & Business General. We have over one million books available in our catalogue for you to explore.

Information

Publisher
Routledge
Year
1999
ISBN
9781134190577
Edition
1

1 Why study information economics?

"There is no doubt about it: we are living in the Information Age," Hal Varian, an eminent economist, writes.1 According to a study by Hal Varian and Peter Lyman,2 the amount of new information stored on print, film, magnetic, and optical storage media in 2002 was about 5 * 1018 bytes, or 5 exabytes (at 1 byte = 8 bit). Five exabytes are equivalent to all words ever spoken by human beings, or to the information contained in 37,000 new libraries the size of the Library of Congress book collections. And the volume of additional information continues to grow by one-third every year.
Information is produced, stored, copied and traded. Information is an economic good and, as we will argue, a strange one. Which other good can be kept and passed on at the same time? Which other good often cannot be destroyed? Which other good cannot be discovered in a person even if the person is scanned with the most advanced technology? Consequently, the first reason for studying the economics of information is:
  • Information is an interesting economic good.
For many people outside of the economics profession, economics is about money, or about getting rich. For most economists (not all of whom have become rich), economics is about understanding "what, how, and for whom" the economy produces—as the 1970 Nobel laureate in economics, Paul Samuelson (born 1915), put it. That is why economists have intensely studied the market, the very mechanism that brings about the what, how, and for whom. The task of the market is far from trivial: "the knowledge of the circumstances of which we must make use never exists in concentrated or integrated form, but solely as the dispersed bits of incomplete and frequently contradictory knowledge which all the separate individuals possess" as Friedrich A. Von Hayek (1945), another Nobel laureate, remarked 60 years ago. The true "economic problem", therefore, is how to aggregate dispersed information. Our second reason for studying the economics of information then is:
  • Economics is about information.
As we said before, information is a good, and the market brings all the tiny individual parts of this good together to express information in the price system. It is the scent of profit with which the market seduces us to collect and convey information. An illustration is the Waterloo legend concerning the origins of Nathan Rothschild's fortune (see Box 1.1).
Box 1.1 The Nathan Rothschild Waterloo legend
A famous (and fictitious) legend has it that Baron Nathan de Rothschild made a fortune on the London stock exchange, as he was the first to learn about Napoléon Bonaparte's defeat in the final battle of Waterloo (1815) against the united British and Prussian armies, under Wellington and Blücher respectively.3 Rothschild had established a courier system by which he learnt the outcome of the battle a full day earlier than the British war office. Upon hearing of Napoléon's defeat, Rothschild allegedly went to the London exchange, put on a sombre face and started to sell British stock and government debt. Other traders, assuming that Rothschild had bad news and trying to free-ride on it, also began to sell. Prices tumbled, and Rothschild's straw men could buy cheaply, leaving the cunning baron with a fortune.
Assume for a moment that the story is true. Imagine you are a trader and you see Rothschild sell. You know that Rothschild knows how the battle ended. Should you follow his lead and sell too? Is that not what Rothschild had expected to happen? After all, he knew that other traders knew about his information advantage. Thinking just one step further, a cunning trader might have bought. And if all traders had, Rothschild would have lost, rather than have made his fortune.
As the example shows, information has highly strategic aspects. It is not only important to know about facts, but also about what others know, and about what they know about what we know. Information strategy is a tricky business, as Lady Kunigund (see Box 1.2) shows.
Box 1.2 The Glove (Friedrich Schiller)
The ballad Der Handschuh (The Glove; quoted from an anonymous translation) was written in 1797 by the German dramatist Friedrich Schiller. In this ballad the king and his court are seated around an arena filled with lions, tigers and leopards. Lady Kunigund tosses her glove among the beasts and turns to Knight Delorges:
"Sir Knight, if the love that thou feel'st in thy breast
Is as warm as thou'rt wont at each moment to swear,
Pick up, I pray thee, the glove that lies there!"
Delorges casually descends among the animals, picks up the glove, and returns amid shouts of praise and wonder.
The praise of his courage each mouth employs;
Meanwhile, with a tender look of love,
The promise to him of coming joys,
Fair Kunigund welcomes him back to his place.
But he threw the glove point-blank in her face:
"Lady, no thanks from thee I'll receive!"
And that selfsame hour he took his leave.
Lady Kunigund discovered another crucial aspect of information: You cannot obtain information from others without giving some information. By asking for proof of love, Lady Kunigund proved the absence of true love on her part. The act of observing alters the reality being observed; this can be seen as the equivalent of Heisenberg's uncertainty principle in information economics.
Baron Rothschild and Lady Kunigund are just two examples of the very special and important role information plays in economic and strategic situations. They also highlight that information is an unruly kind of economic good and that its aggregation by individuals or by the market may not always ran so smoothly. This bring us to the third reason for studying information economics:
  • Information is of strategic importance.
Information is at the root of many real world phenomena and problems. In this book we will encounter a number of examples: Why doctors do not always tell the truth; why examiners hate mediocre papers; why entrepreneurs are constructive destroyers; why health insurance may not work; why genetic testing may destroy welfare; why workers subsidize professors; why prices are sticky; why winning an auction may be bad news; why companies should not have an incentive to lie; why banks are supervised and why they sometimes fall victims to runs; and why we sometimes prefer to turn a blind eye to the information at our disposal.
Over the last two decades, economists have devoted a great deal of time and effort to improving their understanding of the role of information, thus building on seminal contributions to the field from the early 1970s (see Chapter 2). Information economics is no longer in its infancy; it has now reached its adolescent phase. In conjunction with the above argument the fourth reason for studying information economics is therefore:
  • Information economics is a young field with practical relevance in many contexts.
Information economics may even be somewhat en vogue. This should not come as a surprise. Already many years ago, the fashion industry, known for its infallible sense for cultural undercurrents, gave us two fragrances called Knowing (1988), and Guess (1990). Linking scent to information, the fashion leaders also expressed a deep understanding of the importance of information in human relations. This importance could be a covert fifth reason for studying information economics.
In a music shop, a young man is leisurely browsing through the racks of CDs. A woman, evidently in a hurry, brusquely pushes past him. "Sony!" he says, "Maybe I could help you—if you don't mind telling me what you're looking for." "Don't You Know Who I Think I Was?", she replies. "Pardon?" "Don't You Know Who I Think I Was?" Looking rather perplexed, he answers, "No, I have to say I don't!" "Sorry, I should explain. You asked me what I was looking for. So I told you the title of the album. Some songs from the 80s."
Unfortunately they cannot find the album. "Fancy a coffee?" the woman asks. "Great idea", the man replies, "I'm Bob, by the way." "Pleased to meet you, Bob. I'm Alice."

2 How to use this book

2 A The purpose of the book

This textbook is aimed at students of economics, business and related fields, particularly those in their third or fourth year of undergraduate study However, we believe that the book could also be beneficial to Masters and even PhD students. Many parts were written as to be comprehensible also to a second-year undergraduate student equipped with some rudimentary knowledge of game theory and basic microeconomics, not to mention a healthy dose of curiosity.
The goal of the book is to introduce students to the concepts of information economics which have developed during the so-called "information revolution" of the last thirty years (see Box 2.1). Presenting a new field is like showing a foreign visitor around one's home town or country. Should we go by taxi, allowing us to take the visitor anywhere? Or, should we recommend the sight-seeing bus, which does not give the traveller much flexibility (except falling asleep, perhaps), but guarantees stop-offs at a few important sites?
In this book we opted for the sight-seeing approach. We try to give readers an idea of some of the central ideas behind information economics, the equivalents of the Eiffel Tower, Notre Dame, or the Louvre. Once readers are familiar with the structure of the field and its most important features, they can strike out on their own: either taking a taxi and looking at some places of private interest or embarking on the lone walk of research ...
Box 2.1 The information revolution in economics
Economists have long been interested in the role of information in the economy. Yet, much of economic theory was developed under the assumption that individuals make their decisions based on perfect knowledge. This assumption enables us to model the economy in terms of a general equilibrium framework, known as the Arrow-Debreu model. Such a model is able to cope with uncertainty, insofar as it is of the well-behaved kind, under which all agents believe in the same probabilities for the same events.
In the second half of the twentieth century, advances in telecommunications led to a growing interest in "information theory", first among physicists, and later among economists. Physicists and engineers tackled questions such as how information could be described or measured, often with a view to its optimal transmission through a given channel, like a cable. At the same time, mathematicians developed the basics of strategic behavior theory, better known as game theory. If one single event should symbolize this development, it would be the formulation of the equilibrium in a non-cooperative game by John Nash in 1950.
In the...

Table of contents