Trade Openness and China's Economic Development
eBook - ePub

Trade Openness and China's Economic Development

Miaojie Yu

Share book
  1. 406 pages
  2. English
  3. ePUB (mobile friendly)
  4. Available on iOS & Android
eBook - ePub

Trade Openness and China's Economic Development

Miaojie Yu

Book details
Book preview
Table of contents
Citations

About This Book

With the expansion of globalization, international trade has played an increasingly significant role, especially for developing countries. As the largest developing country, China has made a lot of efforts to integrate to the global market since its Open and Reform Policy in 1978 and has become the second largest economy in world. So what is the effect of China's trade-oriented strategy for the country and the world? How did it improve the country's economic development? These are some critical questions this book discusses.

This book utilizes classic Western economic models to examine how China's openness policies have affected the manufacturing upgrading and economic development of the country. A large amount of micro-level empirical evidence is added to support the conclusion.

Scholars and students in economics and business will benefit from this book. Also, it will appeal to readers interested in policy making and Chinese studies.

Frequently asked questions

How do I cancel my subscription?
Simply head over to the account section in settings and click on “Cancel Subscription” - it’s as simple as that. After you cancel, your membership will stay active for the remainder of the time you’ve paid for. Learn more here.
Can/how do I download books?
At the moment all of our mobile-responsive ePub books are available to download via the app. Most of our PDFs are also available to download and we're working on making the final remaining ones downloadable now. Learn more here.
What is the difference between the pricing plans?
Both plans give you full access to the library and all of Perlego’s features. The only differences are the price and subscription period: With the annual plan you’ll save around 30% compared to 12 months on the monthly plan.
What is Perlego?
We are an online textbook subscription service, where you can get access to an entire online library for less than the price of a single book per month. With over 1 million books across 1000+ topics, we’ve got you covered! Learn more here.
Do you support text-to-speech?
Look out for the read-aloud symbol on your next book to see if you can listen to it. The read-aloud tool reads text aloud for you, highlighting the text as it is being read. You can pause it, speed it up and slow it down. Learn more here.
Is Trade Openness and China's Economic Development an online PDF/ePUB?
Yes, you can access Trade Openness and China's Economic Development by Miaojie Yu in PDF and/or ePUB format, as well as other popular books in Economía & Economía del desarrollo. We have over one million books available in our catalogue for you to explore.

Information

Publisher
Routledge
Year
2019
ISBN
9781000763331

Part I
Macro-perspective

1
Industrial structural upgrading and poverty reduction in China
1

1.1 Introduction

In the three decades of economic reforms since 1979, China has successfully maintained a 9.9-percent annual gross domestic product (GDP) growth rate and registered a 16.3-percent annual growth rate for international trade (Lin, 2010). China has already taken over Japan as the second largest economy in the world, and it will become the largest economy by the 2020s in terms of purchasing power parity (PPP).2 Despite being negatively affected by the recent global financial crisis, China still surpassed Germany as the largest exporter in the world in 2009, and it is currently recognized as the largest “world factory.” China has also succeeded in reducing poverty. In 1979, China was one of the poorest agrarian countries in the world, with a per-capita annual income of US$243 at 1979’s exchange rates,3 which was about one-third of the average in sub-Saharan countries. Only three decades later, China’s per-capita GDP increased to approximately $5,000 in 2011, and China became an upper-middle income country, according to the classification of the World Bank.
China’s rapid growth was achieved through a dramatic structural transformation, which can be observed from changes in the sectoral composition of GDP. In 1978, primary goods accounted for 28.2 percent of GDP, and agricultural exports for around 35 percent of China’s entire exports. In sharp contrast, the proportion of primary industry in China’s GDP today has shrunk to 11 percent, and agricultural exports only account for less than 3.5 percent of China’s total exports. With the declining share of agricultural goods, manufacturing exports have increased dramatically in the last three decades, increasing from 65 percent in 1980 to approximately 96.5 percent in 2009 (Yu, 2011a). Similar changes occurred in the composition of employment. The share of the labor force in primary industry declined from 70.5 percent in 1978 to 38.1 in 2009 whereas the labor force in secondary industry increased from 17.3 percent to 27.8 percent in the same period.
Industrial upgrading is also a remarkable feature of China’s economy since its economic reform. As discussed later, China’s industrial upgrading exhibits four clear phases. In the first phase (1978 to 1985), China still relied on producing and exporting resource-based goods, such as oil and gasoline. The second phase (1986 to 1995) witnessed a fast growth of labor-intensive exports. In the third phase (1996 to 2000), the main export from China was electrical machinery and transport equipment. At the same time, China also imported a large volume of machinery. The increasingly important role of intra-industry trade can mainly be attributed to China’s successful industrial upgrading and the prevalent processing trade that aligned production with China’s comparative advantage. The latest phase, which began in 2001, has recorded a fast export growth in high-technology products, such as life-science equipment.
China’s successful structural transformation and industrial upgrading beg the question of how it developed from a backward, closed, and agrarian economy to an open, competitive world factory. In this chapter we will discuss what happened to China’s production structure and industrial upgrading. How did China successfully upgrade its manufacturing structure in the last three decades? What are the fundamental driving forces behind the transformation? Furthermore, to what extent did the rapid structural transformation and industrial upgrading help to foster employment and reduce poverty in China? Finally, what lessons can be learned from China’s successful structural transformation and industrial upgrading?
Our basic argument is that China’s rapid industrial upgrading and its consequent poverty reduction are mainly attributed to the adoption of an appropriate development strategy, which is a comparative-advantage-following (CAF) development strategy, driven by its factor endowments (Lin, 2003, 2009, 2012, Lin et al., 2004). As China is a labor abundant country, the labor-intensive industries can be competitive and viable if the market is not distorted. The latent comparative advantage of the Chinese economy was suppressed before its economic reform because China’s government adopted a heavy industry-oriented development strategy. As such the development strategy was comparative-advantage-defying (CAD), and China’s government set up an organic but deeply distorted system to support economic development, with priority on heavy industries. Under this system, the prices of input factors and output were set by a planned administration system and were hence distorted. Firms were deprived of production autonomy and lacked incentives. Efficiency was low. Accordingly, the industrial structure could not be upgraded. As heavy industries are capital intensive and incapable of absorbing more labor, employment opportunities in the industrial sector were limited in spite of large investment. Finally, as the state required its puppet-like state-owned enterprises (SOEs) to squeeze as much profit as possible out of production, wages for workers were suppressed at a low level, and the prices of agricultural products were set with unfavorable terms of trade against peasants. Both forces made the Chinese people maintain a low living standard, and severe poverty could not be alleviated.
After its economic take-off, China adopted a CAF development strategy. The two main aspects of this strategy are both the adoption of the dual-track reform to provide temporary protection or subsidies to the traditional and old sectors and the encouragement to develop new viable sectors aligned with its comparative advantage driven by its factor endowments. The dual-track reforms, including price reform of output and input factor markets as well as foreign trade and exchange rate reforms, were essentially Pareto optimal. All reforms started by allowing the existence of two tracks, that is, one dominated by the state and the other oriented to the market. The two tracks subsequently converged and unified to a market track only. Similarly, to avoid the collapse of SOEs due to the shock of rapid reform, SOE reform began with granting management autonomy and then moved to institutional transitions. More importantly, new firms and industries aligned with China’s comparative advantage were greatly encouraged. The growth of China’s town village enterprises (TVEs) serves as an excellent example. The government’s successful growth identification and facilitation played a vital role in transforming its economic structures and upgrading its manufacturing structures because they overcame asymmetric information, coordination failure, and even externality appropriateness that are associated with market mechanism (Lin, 2012).
The structural transformation and industrial upgrading also have significant effects on employment generation and poverty reduction. With structural transformation, the share of the primary sector in GDP declined dramatically, and the shares of the secondary sector and, especially, the tertiary sector consequently increased. As a result, laborers moved out of the primary sector and earned higher wages in the secondary and tertiary sectors. With the correction of the distortion in input factors, the unfavorable terms of trade against the peasants were redressed. The boom of TVEs also provided more employment opportunities for rural people with high-income earnings. The government’s forceful facilitation in the rural area also improved both hard and soft infrastructures. The three factors mentioned earlier improved the living standard and dramatically reduced poverty in the rural area. The industrial upgrading also improved the living standards of workers in the urban area. With a CAF development strategy, labor-intensive industries developed rapidly, which in turn created new working opportunities. After three decades of reforms, SOEs were downsized in terms of numbers and output, but their performance was in a much better shape after efficiency increased and workers’ initiatives were stimulated. As a result, workers’ living standards were improved in the urban area, along with structural transformation and industrial upgrading.
Other developing countries can learn two main points from China’s economic miracle. First, to upgrade industrial structure successfully, a developing country must adopt a CAF development strategy based on its factor endowment. Second, despite a free, fair, and competitive market mechanism, governments of developing countries are suggested to play a proactive role in facilitating structural transformation and industrial upgrading. A useful framework for growth identification and facilitation with several key suggestions is provided and discussed in this study, as policy makers usually find identifying growth opportunities difficult.
The remainder of this chapter is organized as follows. Section 1.2 introduces the conditions faced by China’s manufacturing industry before China’s economic reform in 1978. Section 1.3 discusses the trends and characteristics of China’s industrialization and manufacturing structural upgrading since its take-off. Section 1.4 examines the main factors, namely, policy setting, accounting for rapid industrial growth, and structural upgrading. Section 1.5 investigates the effect of industrial growth and manufacturing structural change on employment generation, following a careful scrutiny of the relationship between shifts in manufacturing employment and poverty reduction. Based on China’s experience, Section 1.6 discusses the main points that other developing countries can learn from China. Finally, Section 1.7 concludes and provides some suggestions for China’s further reform.

1.2 China’s economy before the reform

Before its economic reform, China was a poor, agrarian economy. In 1952, agriculture accounted for 57.7 percent of China’s GDP and absorbed 83.5 percent of China’s employed labor. Per-capita GDP was very low. In particular, per-capita agricultural and industrial output was RMB143 (or equivalently $65 at 1952 price).4 Before the economic reform, a distorted industrial structure suppressed the development of China’s economy, which in turn generated a closed economy and deep poverty, and a distorted income distribution.
Similar to the leaders in many other developing countries established after World War II, China’s leaders adopted a heavy-industry oriented development strategy after gaining political independence in 1949. However, heavy industries are capital-intensive, and China was essentially a capital-scarce agrarian economy. Such stark difference between factor endowments and development strategy made allocating resources through the market mechanism impossible for China. Instead, a development strategy that prioritized heavy industry, which is a CAD strategy, distorted product and factor prices, and it had to rely on a highly centralized planned resource allocation mechanism. Correspondently, the government had to set up a puppet-like micromanagement system. These three elements in China’s economy before its reform are referred to as the trinity of the traditional economic system (Lin et al., 2004) and introduced as follows.
First, China’s government had to distort macroeconomic policies that suppressed interest rates, exchange rates, wages, prices of raw materials and intermediates inputs, and even agricultural prices to perform its heavy industry-oriented development strategy (Lin, 2003). Projects in heavy industries require much capital, which was scarce in China. In response to the strong demand for capital, the government had to control interest rates to reduce the cost of capital. In addition, heavy industries also require capital-intensive intermediate goods and equipment, which had to be imported because China, an agrarian economy, could not produce such goods at that time. Therefore, sufficient foreign exchange reserves are a priori for projects on heavy industries. However, foreign exchange in China was also scarce because China’s exports, if any, were limited to natural resources and low value-adding agricultural products before the economic reform. China’s government had to overvalue its own currency against the dollar to lower the cost of imported intermediate inputs. China appreciated its currency (RMB) from RMB4.2 per dollar in 1950 to RMB1.7 per dollar, a 250 percent appreciation during this period.
Raising sufficient funds to support heavy industries was difficult because China was an agrarian economy. The only way to accumulate capital for heavy industries is to reduce the cost of various input factors. In accordance with the suppression of the interest rate, the government also set low nominal wages for urban workers. The wages were independent of the workers’ effort, but the wages varied by rank and seniority. Before 197...

Table of contents