A Macroeconomic Analysis of Profit
eBook - ePub

A Macroeconomic Analysis of Profit

  1. 174 pages
  2. English
  3. ePUB (mobile friendly)
  4. Available on iOS & Android
eBook - ePub

A Macroeconomic Analysis of Profit

Book details
Book preview
Table of contents
Citations

About This Book

Based on the observation of economic reality, this book provides for the foundations of a new structure of national payment systems. Specifically, to this end, a rigorous accounting for money transactions, savings, and invested profit is suggested, with a major aim to settle sustainable lending levels.

Profit lies at the heart of economic activities. Indeed, companies, from small to large, seek net gains to remunerate shareholders and to increase their assets. Yet, economists are far from sharing a common theory of profit. Using mathematical tools and a discursive approach, this book contributes to the debates in such regard, in the attempt to provide new answers to old economic issues. What is macroeconomic profit? Is there any relationship between wages, lending, and profit?

This book is an accesible resource for economists and financial experts as well as global economics students, researchers, academics and historians alike. It will challenge policy-makers and professionals and lead them on a thought-provoking journey through the realm of macroeconomics.

Frequently asked questions

Simply head over to the account section in settings and click on “Cancel Subscription” - it’s as simple as that. After you cancel, your membership will stay active for the remainder of the time you’ve paid for. Learn more here.
At the moment all of our mobile-responsive ePub books are available to download via the app. Most of our PDFs are also available to download and we're working on making the final remaining ones downloadable now. Learn more here.
Both plans give you full access to the library and all of Perlego’s features. The only differences are the price and subscription period: With the annual plan you’ll save around 30% compared to 12 months on the monthly plan.
We are an online textbook subscription service, where you can get access to an entire online library for less than the price of a single book per month. With over 1 million books across 1000+ topics, we’ve got you covered! Learn more here.
Look out for the read-aloud symbol on your next book to see if you can listen to it. The read-aloud tool reads text aloud for you, highlighting the text as it is being read. You can pause it, speed it up and slow it down. Learn more here.
Yes, you can access A Macroeconomic Analysis of Profit by Andrea Carrera in PDF and/or ePUB format, as well as other popular books in Business & Business General. We have over one million books available in our catalogue for you to explore.

Information

Publisher
Routledge
Year
2019
ISBN
9781351213332
Edition
1

Chapter 1

Money, production, and profit

Households, companies, and banks mainly interact the one with the others so as to pay out wages, to transfer monetary savings, as well as to allow for consumption. Wages and corporate gains are the motor driving individuals, companies, and banks to produce, distribute, and purchase the national product. In this context, money is a required component of any economic system. Yet, economists disagree with each other about the way in which economic players interact as well as about the nature of monetary and real incomes. Thus, this chapter shall propose a study of production, consumption, and banking, in hopes of a new consensus on the basic laws underlying economic phenomena. This chapter aims to prepare the ground for a study of corporate profits. In this light, the investigation shall seek to explain the relation between money and the real economy, focusing on productive activities, on consumption, and on the role of commercial banks as intermediaries between households and companies. An inquiry shall also be made about the historical and theoretical scope of central banks, with particular regard to the Bank of England and to the Federal Reserve System. What are the laws of production, consumption, and banking? What are the functions of commercial and central banks? What is the link between households, companies, and banks?

Bank money and the real economy

Production, consumption, and commercial banks

Traditionally, economists have thought of money as the currency in circulation; that is, banknotes and coins. It comes as no surprise, then, that most theories treat money as a physical object. Even at our times, whenever thinking of money, the one-dollar bill springs to mind. However, currency in circulation is just one side of the story. After all, today’s massive use of electronic means of payment shows that scriptural money is by far larger in amount than banknotes and coins. One can even go further by asserting that some economies are transitioning very quickly toward a cashless future. On this regard, for instance, Sweden is in the lead. As argued by Wheatley (2017) in a study for the International Monetary Fund, banknotes and coins account for only 15% of payments in Sweden, a country where cash is used by less than half of commercial banks and has fallen ‘by nearly 15 percent between 2007 and 2015. Even homeless sellers of Stockholm’s street magazine accept mobile payments’ (Wheatley 2017: 32–3). What is money, then? What relation holds between money and output? What is the relation between money, production, and consumption?
History influenced the general opinion about money. As recalled by Smith in his Wealth of Nations (1776 [1981]: 41), the incomes of the Saxons, in ancient times, did not consist of money, but ‘in kind, that is, in victuals and provisions of all sorts’; metal money was started being used only later on, under William the Conqueror. Iron was already used by the inhabitants of Sparta to facilitate the commerce of goods, and it was Servio Tullio who first coined money in Rome, using ‘a Roman pound of good copper’ (Smith 1776 [1981]: 42). Also, at the time of Alexander the First, the Scots already used ‘a pound of silver of the same weight and fineness with the English pound sterling’ (Smith 1776 [1981]: 41). Over time, gold, silver, and paper money, for instance, have been used by the richest nations to facilitate production and trade.
Then, it is not surprising that money has usually been identified with a physical medium. Broadly speaking, economists (see, for instance, Phelps 1961; Friedman and Schwartz 1963; Brunner and Meltzer 1971; Phelps and Taylor 1977) usually refer to money as a stock whose quantity would determine the amount of money supply in circulation and under the form of demand deposits (for recent critiques of the quantitative theory of money and monetarism, see for instance Keynes 1936 [1964]; Desai 1981; Cencini 2005; Krugman 2016; Rochon and Rossi 2018; Rossi’s forthcoming a, forthcoming b analyses). The conception of money as a physical medium of exchange and means of payment is so widely diffused that its status is almost that of an axiom.
Interestingly, according to some authors, money is not of a physical nature, but scriptural; that is, a number in bank books without intrinsic value. On this regard, Bernard Schmitt (1960, 1975, 1984, 1986, 1996) was followed, among others, by Alain Parguez (1975, 1996, 2001), Alain BarrĂšre (1979, 1990a, 1990b), Alvaro Cencini (1984, 1988, 2001, 2005), and Augusto Graziani (1989, 2003). As Rossi (2007: 18) points out:
[m]oney does not need to be reified into a precious metal in order for it to be a means of payment: it would be enough [
] a double-entry book by means of which [
] economic transactions are recorded and settled with a mere book-entry device.
According to these authors, money is of a numerical nature, with no intrinsic value. Money is ‘a pure symbol, a stroke of the pen in the bank’s balance sheet’ (Realfonzo 1998: 43). It is on double-entry bookkeeping, which has existed since the 13th century, that this analysis of money is founded.
As odd or against the tide as it may appear, money is far from being the physical object described in most of the economic literature. Banking systems are based on scriptural money, which is issued by commercial banks, in the first stance, so as to allow for companies to pay out wages. The creation of money takes place alongside productive activities; better said, production is the raison d’ĂȘtre of money creation. Hence, production and money creation must always be understood on logical grounds: without money, output would have no monetary value; without output, there would be no reason for money to be issued.
Think of a commercial bank and name it Nantucket Bank, after one of the oldest commercial banks in America. As any commercial bank, Nantucket Bank holds assets and liabilities corresponding to the credits and debits toward its clients. Assets include loans, securities, reserves with the central bank, cash, and other items. Liabilities include deposits, borrowings, and others. As the laws of double-entry bookkeeping require, the amount of assets and the amount of liabilities on any balance sheet must always match. This means that the value of assets is always equal to the value of liabilities.
Now, it is no mystery that loans are granted on the basis of the amount of deposits held by the bank on behalf of its clients, according to the saying ‘deposits make loans’. What is unknown to most people is the fact that a certain kind of loans gives rise to new deposits, according to the saying ‘loans make deposits’. This kind of loan is made thanks to the activation of credit lines, or, in other words, when wages are paid. The payment of wages, in fact, does not rely on previously existing deposits. For the sake of clarity, an example may be of help.
Suppose a firm requests the bank to credit workers’ accounts with wages, relying on a credit line that the firm has previously obtained and backed by securities (on this topic, see for instance Rossi 2007: 25). Workers are credited with wages amounting to $100. The bank grants credit to the firm and simultaneously registers deposits of workers for the same amount. As soon as the payment of wages is made, the stylized balance sheet of Nantucket Bank will be affected as follows (Table 1.1).
Table 1.1 The stylized balance sheet of commercial banks
Nantucket Bank (Massachusetts)
Assets
Liabilities
Loans
∆$100
Deposits
∆$100
Securities
$

Borrowings
$

Reserves with the central bank, cash, other assets
$

Other liabilities
$

Source: author’s elaboration from the Federal Reserve (2016a). ∆ stands for ‘increase’.
As soon as wages are paid to them, workers are credited with an amount of bank deposits that is matched by a net credit of the bank toward the company. This event triggers, so to speak, the creation of wage-income. Resulting from the activation of a credit line, the payment of wages gives rise to an increase in the overall level of the assets and of the liabilities on the books of Nantucket Bank. Wage-income has thus formed. Workers are credited, while the firm is debited. To the bank accounts of workers corresponds a security on the financial market, namely a certificate of deposit, whose real object is the output produced and warehoused within the company. Interestingly, the terms ‘output’, ‘product’, and ‘goods’ also refer to services, for ‘goods and services are both examples of economic goods’ (Solow 2012: 271). The remuneration of workers coincides with the production costs incurred by the company, which are the objective, monetary value of real output. Identifying wages as the measure for output value is equal to defining a product-wages relation where money functions as a unit of account for wages – Keynes (1936 [1964]) used the expression ‘wage-unit’ to refer to the measure of output value. Keynes’s (1936 [1964]: 20) words can easily be borrowed here: ‘the income derived in the aggregate by all the elements in the community in a productive activity necessarily has a value exactly equal to the value of the output’.
Now, the payment of wages always confers to wage-earners as a whole the right to purchase produced output. Whenever wage-earners use their credit cards, for instance, they spend their income to purchase a product or a service. Consumption allows companies to cover the production costs they have sustained on the labor market, also known as the market for productive services. Through consumption, goods and services leave the warehouses of companies and are allocated among their final users to satisfy their needs; the flow of money that is credited on corporate bank accounts allows for a reduction in the debts of companies toward the bank. Again, an example may be of help.
Think of a territory, which we call Nantucket. It well may be an island, an estate, or simply a university classroom. Suppose that Seafarer Co. is the sole company at Nantucket. Wage-earners at Seafarer Co. produce ten tons of seafood chowder. Hence, the output produced at Seafarer Co. is made of chowder. At the beginning of January, Seafarer Co. obtains the opening of a credit line by Nantucket Bank. At the end of the month, the credit line shall be activated and wages shall be paid. For the sake of simplicity, suppose all entries in Nantucket Bank’s balance sheet to be nil. Suppose also that only scriptural money is used; that is, neither coins nor banknotes exist (nonetheless, some comments on banknotes and coins shall be made further on). At Nantucket, wage-earners include all kinds of workers, without any social class distinction: for instance, workmen, employees, managers, consultants, and so on. In this sense, workers include entrepreneurs. The entrepreneur indeed should be regarded as a worker providing his services. ‘It is preferable to regard labour, including, of course, the personal services of the entrepreneur and his assistants, as the sole factor of production’ (Keynes 1936 [1964]: 213–14). It has to be noted that this is far from meaning that the company makes no profit. As argued later on, income is made not only of wages, but also of profit. In the real world indeed, as soon as output is sold, companies usually expect to make profits. Suppose also that, at Nantucket, for a number of reasons, some individuals do not work and receive a share of wages from wage-earners. For instance, some children receive tips by their parents to buy fresh chowder at the local market. Thus, it shall be assumed that bank deposits are constituted in favor not only of wage-earners, but of households broadly speaking.
Money is simultaneously a company’s debt and a credit of workers considered as a whole, both toward the banking system (Schmitt 1966: 286–7). The remuneration of labor (nominal wages) constitutes the monetary form of global output, and, if companies’ profit is zero, it confers to workers the right to purchase the whole of real product. An example may help clarifying this point. Suppose that households spend the totality of wages altogether to purchase seafood chowder. In this context, if the company does not seek to gain from the sale, the selling price of output shall be equal to production costs. Households shall purchase the totality of consumption-goods. The price of $100 being equal to production costs of $100, households dispose of the sufficient and necessary income to purchase ten tons of seafood chowder. Nothing remains unsold after the sale.
Accounting entries in Table 1.2 show this process. Entry 1 refers to the payment of wages. Seafarer Co. is debited, and households are credited by the bank. This is respectively shown in the assets and in the liabilities of the bank’s book. Entry 2 concerns income expenditure. When households spend their monetary income, Seafarer Co. covers its production costs and is able to pay back its debt to the bank. As soon as all the debit-credit relationships are extinguished, as shown in entry 3, monetary income is finally spent, and households benefit from using the goods they have purchased. The asset and the liabilities in the balance sheet of Nantucket Bank decrease accordingly.
Table 1.2 Wage payment and consumption
Nantucket Bank (Massachusetts)
Assets
Liabilities
(1) Seafarer Co.
$100
Households
$100
(2) Households
$100
Seafarer Co.
$100
(3)
$0
$0
Source: author’s elaboration from Cencini and Rossi (2015).
What is worth inferring with the help of double-entry bookkeeping is that the nature of money is twofold, for it is a numerical flow (money-as-a-flow or vehicular money) and a numerical stock (money-as-a-stock).
On the one hand, vehicular money is used as a means of payment in every single transaction. Money, as a vehicle, is instrumental to credit and to debit the accounts of income-earners. For instance, in the banking system a bookkeeping entry accounting f...

Table of contents

  1. Cover
  2. Half Title
  3. Series
  4. Title
  5. Copyright
  6. Contents
  7. List of figures
  8. List of tables
  9. Foreword
  10. Foreword and acknowledgments
  11. Introduction
  12. 1 Money, production, and profit
  13. 2 Classical and neoclassical theories of profit
  14. 3 Keynes and Keynesian theories of profit
  15. 4 New directions in the theory of profit
  16. 5 Profit, lending, and banking reforms
  17. Conclusion
  18. Bibliography
  19. Name index
  20. Subject index