Management in Networks
eBook - ePub

Management in Networks

  1. 150 pages
  2. English
  3. ePUB (mobile friendly)
  4. Available on iOS & Android
eBook - ePub

Management in Networks

Book details
Book preview
Table of contents
Citations

About This Book

Getting what you want – even if you are the boss – isn't always easy. Almost every organization, big or small, works among a network of competing interests. Whether it's governments pushing through policies, companies trying to increase profits, or even families deciding where to move house, rarely can decisions be made in isolation from competing interests both within the organization and outside it.

In this accessible and straightforward account, Hans de Bruijn and Ernst ten Heuvelhof cast light on multi-stakeholder decision-making. Using plain language, they reveal the nuts and bolts of decision-making within the numerous dilemmas and tensions at work. Drawing on a diverse range of illustrative examples throughout, their perceptive analysis examines how different interests can either support or block change, and the strategies available for managing a variety of stakeholders.

The second edition of Management in Networks incorporates a wider spread of international cases, a new chapter giving an overview of different network types, and a new chapter looking at digital governance and the impact of big data on networks.

This insightful text is invaluable reading for students of management and organizational studies, plus practitioners – or actors – operating in a range of contexts.

Frequently asked questions

Simply head over to the account section in settings and click on “Cancel Subscription” - it’s as simple as that. After you cancel, your membership will stay active for the remainder of the time you’ve paid for. Learn more here.
At the moment all of our mobile-responsive ePub books are available to download via the app. Most of our PDFs are also available to download and we're working on making the final remaining ones downloadable now. Learn more here.
Both plans give you full access to the library and all of Perlego’s features. The only differences are the price and subscription period: With the annual plan you’ll save around 30% compared to 12 months on the monthly plan.
We are an online textbook subscription service, where you can get access to an entire online library for less than the price of a single book per month. With over 1 million books across 1000+ topics, we’ve got you covered! Learn more here.
Look out for the read-aloud symbol on your next book to see if you can listen to it. The read-aloud tool reads text aloud for you, highlighting the text as it is being read. You can pause it, speed it up and slow it down. Learn more here.
Yes, you can access Management in Networks by Hans de Bruijn,Ernst Ten Heuvelhof in PDF and/or ePUB format, as well as other popular books in Business & Business General. We have over one million books available in our catalogue for you to explore.

Information

Publisher
Routledge
Year
2018
ISBN
9781315452999
Edition
2

1 Our interconnected world and what it means for decision and policy making

An interconnected world

We live in an interconnected world (Castells, 2011)). The internet and the globalisation of the economy mean everything is connected to everything else. That sometimes has unforeseen and dramatic consequences. Take, for example, the economic crisis at the beginning of the twenty-first century. The fact that Europe is a system of interconnected economies is why problems in the small Greek economy could throw the entire euro zone into crisis. The housing bubble in America caused a global economic crisis. Cybercrime is an international game played out in a web of technology and actors in which the villains are thousands of kilometres away from their victims.
Chaos theory uses a well-known metaphor to clarify these processes in an interconnected world: the ‘butterfly effect’. A butterfly in Brazil flaps its wings and causes a tornado in Texas months later. The initial movement – the flap of the butterfly’s wings – causes only a tiny effect. But that is just the first of a chain of effects that gets bigger and bigger until eventually a tornado develops in Texas. Who imagines in advance that a butterfly, thousands of kilometres away, could cause a tornado? Who had ever thought that the small Greek economy could send the entire euro zone into a crisis? These are phenomena that are inherent to an interconnected world and that in many cases we can only recognise in hindsight rather than predict in advance.
In this book we will discuss the question of what this interconnected world means for change processes, for policy-making and for decision-making. In a nutshell: What does it mean for governance? It will become clear that a linear, systematic approach to governance is impossible in an interconnected world. So, the question is, how can governance be made possible?
Toward this end, in this first chapter we will unravel the essence of an interconnected world. How is this world structured, and what does this structure mean for the progress of decision-making processes in networks? With the help of these insights we can then, in the following chapters of this book, explore how governance can be substantiated in an interconnected world.

The structure of an interconnected world: three characteristics

Table 1.1 shows the three most important characteristics of the interconnected world – at least if we look at them from the perspective of governance.
Table 1.1 Main characteristics of an interconnected world
Characteristic of an interconnected world … instead of
Interdependencies Hierarchy
Unstructured ‘wicked’ problems Structured problems
Dynamics Stability

First characteristic: Interdependencies

The first important characteristic of an interconnected world is that, indeed, it is inhabited by a large number of parties or actors (we will use both these terms alternately throughout this book): governments, companies, not-for-profit organisations, citizens. These actors have differing interests and are dependent on each other. These interdependencies are inherent to a high-tech society with its super-specialisms: the more specialisms, the more dependencies, – including its dependence on the internet. In the web of dependencies thus created nobody can achieve anything without the support of others. These interdependencies result in a multitude of relationships between the actors. Together all these relationships form what we call a network.
The world as a whole has become a network, but nations, regions and local communities are equally a network. When decisions must be taken, for example about roads or airports, we very often see that many local players, with differing interests, are involved. In this context, think of certain organisations, such as municipalities, companies, local action groups and environmentalists. However, the impact of the network concept goes even further. Even the organisations that form the actors in a network are often networks themselves. An organisation such as a hospital, a law firm or an engineering consultancy comprises highly trained professionals, with very different specialisms, who are dependent on each other. The professionals are dependent on the management, but the management is equally dependent on the professionals who possess the expertise and knowledge the managers do not have.
A network can be ideal-typed as the opposite of a hierarchy. A hierarchy is a vertical, pyramid-like structure in which there is a person or group that is in charge and that ultimately makes the decisions. All the other actors are subordinate to this group or person, so there are vertical relationships of superordination and subordination. In a network there is no such thing as a vertical structure. There are many players, nobody can say that he or she is ‘in charge’, and the relationships are horizontal not vertical.
To understand the complexity of the network of interdependencies a number of other characteristics of networks are important.

Types of interdependencies

In the first place: interdependencies can take all kinds of forms.
• Bilateral or multilateral dependencies: Dependencies can exist between two parties but also between more than two parties.
• Single or multidimensional dependencies: Dependencies can relate to one dimension (for example, money) but also to several dimensions (money, information, authorities, relationships).
• Synchronous versus asynchronous dependencies: Actors can at one point in time all be mutually dependent on each other, but the dependencies can also be spread out over time. Today the first actor is dependent on the second actor, but a few months later this second actor is dependent on the first actor.
• Static versus dynamic dependencies. A dependency is dynamic if it changes over the course of time. A party can occupy a dominant position in a network, but that dominant position can become stronger or weaker as time goes by. A static dependency is not subject to change.
In many networks of interdependencies the dependencies are multilateral, multidimensional, asynchronous and dynamic. That makes decision-making and changes in these networks extremely complex, but we’ll come back to that later.

Different interdependencies per topic

A second important aspect of interdependencies is that they can differ per topic. We can use a regional authority as an example. The regional authority is dependent on municipalities, the central government and private parties – and all these actors are, in turn, dependent on the regional authority. The ‘region’ focuses on physical infrastructure, which involves many different parties who together form a network of interdependencies. In this network the region has a degree of dominance, but the region also deals with nature and the environment. Once again other parties are also involved – some are the same as for infrastructure, some are different – and in this network the region may not have the same degree of dominance. As a result the decision-making processes in the infrastructure network and the nature and environment network may be very different. It may also be the case that certain parties are involved in both networks and this can also influence the decision-making. Coming off the worst in the decision-making regarding infrastructure can affect a party’s attitude when it comes to decisions about nature and the environment. This makes decision-making more complex, not only because the network differs per issue but also because certain parties will want to link the decision-making related to one issue to the decision-making related to the other issue.

Interdependencies don’t always reveal themselves

The interdependencies have already created a very complex picture: There are many kinds of dependencies, they can differ per topic, and some people link these topics together. We can add a third factor into the mix: Not all the actors in a network always know what the reciprocal dependencies are. For example, a region may think a municipality holds a weak position in a network whereas, in fact, it holds a very strong position. A region may not know, or may not know with sufficient precision, an actor’s views of and interests in a network. Certainly when it comes to more complex networks (many actors, many kinds of dependencies and many links to other networks), it is virtually impossible for a single actor to oversee the entire network. If actors are unsure of the position of other actors in a network – position not only in terms of dominance but also in terms of views and interests – it goes without saying that an actor’s perception of the positions of others may be mistaken. A party could be more dominant than expected and a wrong assessment of a party’s power can make the decision-making far more complicated. Different actors can, therefore, also have different perceptions regarding the positions in a network. That, too, does not render decision-making simpler.
Networks of interdependencies are already complex, but they become even more complex when the actors involved can have very different perceptions of the same network.

Second characteristic: Unstructured, wicked problems

A second characteristic of an interconnected world concerns the content of the problems that must be solved in such a world. These problems are often ‘unstructured’ or ‘wicked’ (Rittel & Webber, 1973)). Unstructured problems can be ideal-typed as the opposite of structured problems, which are problems for which there is only one right, or the right, solution. An example of a structured problem is the question, “What does 1+1 make?” The answer is 2 – and that answer is independent of political preferences, interests or dominance. Unstructured problems do not have a single right answer. Why are so many problems unstructured?
To explain this we will use a simple example. A dairy company wants to know which type of packaging for milk is the most environmentally responsible: a cardboard carton, a glass bottle with a deposit or a polycarbonate bottle with a deposit. The dairy company wants to know how each of the three types of packaging scores for what are called the ‘environmental components’: energy usage, water usage, toxicity and waste.
To answer this question, several factors must be inventoried, including the production process of these three types of packaging: Which raw materials are used, and how they are transformed into a packaging? Take the cardboard carton. This requires that a tree be cut down somewhere and then transported to a factory where it is turned into cardboard. The cardboard then goes to a factory where it is made into a carton, and other materials, such as a plastic (polyethylene) coating, are added. The polyethylene has also undergone its own production process, which began with cracking naphtha, so that must also be inventoried.
Let’s suppose the tree is cut down in Sweden, transported to Hamburg to be made into cardboard and then the cardboard goes to a factory in Switzerland where it is made into cartons, and other components, such as the polyethylene coating, are added. To determine the real environmental impact, we must make at least three decisions.
• What data are we going to use? We need, for example, data regarding the number of trees that must be cut down to produce a specified number of cartons. We need data regarding the transportation of the trees: How much energy did it cost?
• Which system boundaries will we apply? Or, to put it another way: How do we demarcate the investigation? The trees are transported by ship. We want to know how much energy that costs. But because maybe there wouldn’t be a ship without trees,, must we now also include the building of the ship when determining the environmental cost of the packaging?
• How do we allocate environmental impact to the packaging? The ship also transports cars and washing machines, so what portion of the necessary energy should be allocated to the washing machines and cars and what portion to the trees?
There are many other questions that could be asked, but in this context what it comes down to is that there isn’t an objective answer to many of the questions. One party opts for one data set, the other party prefers other data set. One party opts for system boundaries that the other party considers too narrow or too wide. The allocation could also be calculated using various different methods.
Let’s now suppose that, when deciding on the packaging, our dairy company has to deal with all kinds of other parties, such as an environmental organisation, a governmental authority and several consumer organisations, and that all these parties have different interests and different opinions about the three decisions to be made. The result can be a major conflict regarding the question of the right data, system boundaries and allocation methods – making an objective answer often impossible. When that is the case, many parties will have a tendency to make choices that suit their own interests or preferences.
But, let’s suppose these parties agree about the data, system boundaries and methods, so they know how the three packaging options score for the environmental components energy usage, water usage, toxicity and waste.
Then we come to the next question: how to weigh the four factors against each other. Is a packaging with a bad score for water and waste, but a good score for energy, better than a packaging that scores bad for energy but excellent for water and neutral for waste? To a great extent this is a normative question – and about this question, too, different parties can have very different opinions without there being any objective judgement in respect of the ‘right’ answer. Think about it: So far we have only looked at the environmental aspects. There are many other aspects, such as safety and cost. How do you deal with a packaging that scores well for environmental impact and cost, but badly for safety issues? That makes it all even more complicated.
The essence of all this is:
• The facts we need to enable us to reach a good decision can either be clear-cut or ambiguous.
• The normative considerations we must weigh in order to reach a good decision may be either objective or subjective.
When the facts are ambiguous and the normative consideration is difficult or impossible to objectify, the result is an unstructured problem. See Table 1.2.
Table 1.2 Unstructured problems
Facts: objectifiable Facts: not objectifiable
Normative consideration: objectifiable
Normative consideration: not objectifiable Unstructured problem
When unstructured problems have to be solved in a network with many actors all with different interests, there is a good chance the actors will disagree about data, system boundaries, methods and the normative weight of different components. Their interests often play a role in this – the manufacturer of one-time-use cardboard packaging looks at environmental analyses in a different way than the manufacturer of reusable polycarbonate bottles. In view of their interest the two manufacturers will be critical of analyses with, for them, disagreeable outcomes. This is not, therefore, merely an outright defence of their own interest – when it comes to unstructured problems, the facts don’t speak for themselves, so there is scope for them to be discussed.

Third characteristic: Dynamics

A third characteristic of the interconnected world is that it is dynamic – the interconnected world is constantly in motion. Dynamic can be idea...

Table of contents

  1. Cover
  2. Half Title
  3. Title Page
  4. Copyright Page
  5. Table of Contents
  6. List of illustrations
  7. Preface
  8. 1. Our interconnected world and what it means for decision and policy making
  9. 2. Srategies for making decisions in networks : The process
  10. 3. Strategies for making decisions in networks : The content
  11. 4. A process, not a project
  12. 5. Smart command and control
  13. 6. Strategic behaviour
  14. 7. Trust and rules of the games
  15. 8. Process and content
  16. Bibliography
  17. Index