Woman's Role in Economic Development
eBook - ePub

Woman's Role in Economic Development

  1. 306 pages
  2. English
  3. ePUB (mobile friendly)
  4. Available on iOS & Android
eBook - ePub

Woman's Role in Economic Development

Book details
Book preview
Table of contents
Citations

About This Book

'Boserup's contribution to our thinking on women's role in development cannot be underestimated. Her keen observations, her use of empirical data and her commitment to greater gender equality are still an inspiration to students, researchers and activists who are interested in a better and more equal world.' From the new Introduction by Nazneen Kanji, Su Fei Tan and Camilla Toulmin

'Women's Role in Economic Development has become a key reference book for anyone - student, scholar, or practitioner - interested in gender and development analyses. This book is important not only because it provided the intellectual underpinning of the Women in Development (WID) analysis, but also because of the lasting influence it had on the development of theoretical, conceptual, and policy thinking in the fields of women, gender, and development. The re-editing of Women's Role in Economic Develop ment, with its new introduction, ensures students, academics, and practitioners continued access to an essential reference for those interested in the women and development literature.' - Gender and Development

This classic text by Ester Boserup was the first investigation ever undertaken into what happens to women in the process of economic and social growth throughout the developing world, thereby serving as an international benchmark. In the context of the ongoing struggle for women's rights, massive urbanization and international efforts to reduce poverty, this book continues to be a vital text for economists, sociologists, development workers, activists and all those who take an active interest in women's social and economic circumstances and problems throughout the world. A substantial new Introduction by Nazneen Kanji, Su Fei Tan and Camilla Toulmin reflects on Boserup's legacy as a scholar and activist, and the continuing relevance of her work. This highlights the key issue of how the role of women in economic development has or has not changed over the past four decades in developing countries, and covers crucial current topics including: women and inequality, international and national migration, conflict, HIV and AIDS, markets and employment, urbanization, leadership, property rights, global processes, including the Millennium Development Goals, and barriers to change.

Frequently asked questions

Simply head over to the account section in settings and click on “Cancel Subscription” - it’s as simple as that. After you cancel, your membership will stay active for the remainder of the time you’ve paid for. Learn more here.
At the moment all of our mobile-responsive ePub books are available to download via the app. Most of our PDFs are also available to download and we're working on making the final remaining ones downloadable now. Learn more here.
Both plans give you full access to the library and all of Perlego’s features. The only differences are the price and subscription period: With the annual plan you’ll save around 30% compared to 12 months on the monthly plan.
We are an online textbook subscription service, where you can get access to an entire online library for less than the price of a single book per month. With over 1 million books across 1000+ topics, we’ve got you covered! Learn more here.
Look out for the read-aloud symbol on your next book to see if you can listen to it. The read-aloud tool reads text aloud for you, highlighting the text as it is being read. You can pause it, speed it up and slow it down. Learn more here.
Yes, you can access Woman's Role in Economic Development by Ester Boserup, Su Fei Tan, Camilla Toulmin in PDF and/or ePUB format, as well as other popular books in Economics & Economic Theory. We have over one million books available in our catalogue for you to explore.

Information

Publisher
Routledge
Year
2013
ISBN
9781134037056
Edition
1
PART I
In the Village
Chapter 1
Male and Female Farming Systems
A main characteristic of economic development is the progress towards an increasingly intricate pattern of labour specialization. In communities at the earliest stages of development, practically all goods and services are produced and consumed within the family group, but with economic development more and more people become specialized in particular tasks and the economic autarky of the family group is superseded by the exchange of goods and services.
But even at the most primitive stages of family autarky there is some division of labour within the family, the main criteria for the division being that of age and sex. Some particularly light tasks, such as guarding domestic animals or scaring away wild animals from the crops, are usually left to children or old persons; certain other tasks are performed only by women, while some tasks are the exclusive responsibility of adult men.
Both in primitive and in more developed communities, the traditional division of labour within the farm family is usually considered ‘natural’ in the sense of being obviously and originally imposed by the sex difference itself. But while the members of any given community may think that their particular division of labour between the sexes is the ‘natural’ one, because it has undergone little or no change for generations, other communities may have completely different ways of dividing the burden of work among the sexes, and they too may find their ways just as ‘natural’.
Many social anthropologists and other scientific observers of human communities have emphasized the similarities in the sex roles in various communities. One very distinguished anthropologist, Margaret Mead, in her book Male and Female, gives this summary description of the sex roles: ‘The home shared by a man or men and female partners, into which men bring the food and women prepare it, is the basic common picture the world over. But this picture can be modified, and the modifications provide proof that the pattern itself is not something deeply biological’.1
It is surprising that Margaret Mead, with her extensive and intensive personal experience of primitive communities throughout the world, should venture upon such a dubious generalization. She is right in describing the preparation of food as a monopoly for women in nearly all communities, but the surmise that the provision of food is a man’s prerogative is unwarranted. In fact, an important distinction can be made between two kinds or patterns of subsistence agriculture: one in which food production is taken care of by women, with little help from men, and one where food is produced by the men with relatively little help from women. As a convenient terminology I propose to denote these two systems as the male and the female systems of farming.
The position of women differs in many basic features in these two community groups. Therefore a study of the role of women in economic development may conveniently begin with an examination of women’s tasks in agricultural production in various parts of the underdeveloped regions of the world.

THE DIVISION OF LABOUR WITHIN AFRICAN AGRICULTURE

Africa is the region of female farming par excellence. In many African tribes, nearly all the tasks connected with food production continue to be left to women. In most of these tribal communities, the agricultural system is that of shifting cultivation: small pieces of land are cultivated for a few years only, until the natural fertility of the soil diminishes. When that happens, i.e. when crop yields decline, the field is abandoned and another plot is taken under cultivation. In this type of agriculture it is necessary to prepare some new plots every year for cultivation by felling trees or removing bush or grass cover. Tree felling is nearly always done by men, most often by young boys of 15 to 18 years, but to women fall all the subsequent operations: the removal and burning of the felled trees; the sowing or planting in the ashes; the weeding of the crop; the harvesting and carrying in the crop for storing or immediate consumption.
Of course, there are exceptions to this general rule. In some African communities with shifting cultivation, the women have some help from the men beyond the felling of trees. For instance, men may hoe the land or take part in the preparatory hoeing before the crops are planted, but even with such help the bulk of the work with the food crops is done by women. In some other tribes, most of the field work is done by the men. Thus, we may identify three main systems of subsistence farming in Africa according to whether the field work is done almost exclusively by women, predominantly by women, and predominantly by men.
The relative importance in the African setting of these three patterns can be gauged from Figure 1. This map was prepared forty years ago by H. Baumann, a German expert on African subsistence farming. It appears that forty years ago female farming with no male help except for the felling of trees predominated in the whole of the Congo region, in large parts of South East and East Africa and in parts of West Africa. Female farming was far more widespread than systems of male farming and it also seems to have been more widespread than systems of predominantly female farming with some help from males in cultivation; this latter type of farming was characteristic of the region immediately south of the Sahara.
Farming systems which are not based on scientific methods and with no modern industrial input are usually described as ‘traditional’. It is widely but mistakenly assumed that such ‘traditional’ systems are necessarily passed on from one generation to the next without ever undergoing changes either in techniques or in the division of labour between the sexes. In historic times, tribes with female farming systems have been known to change over to male systems, and—less frequently—tribes with male farming systems have been known to adopt a female system of farming.2
Changes in the division of labour between men and women seem usually to have been related to changes in population density and in farming techniques. For one reason or other, the tribe may have migrated to another region, or local conditions for agriculture may have changed in the region where the tribe used to live. It might be, for instance, that the forest cover was disappearing as the density of population increased, so that the land had to be cultivated more intensively, with shorter periods of rest.
images
Figure 1 Areas of Female and Male Farming in Africa, Around 1930
With the gradual disappearance of the tree cover, the men’s tasks of felling must decline, as must the opportunities for hunting—another decidedly male form of work. On the other hand, with increasing population density new forest areas become scarce. As the fertility of the old ones diminishes, so will the soil need more careful preparation before it is planted, to offset less frequent periods of lying fallow. In such cases it may be necessary for men to help with the hoeing, or even to take over this operation completely from the women; a predominantly female farming system can thus change to one where the two sexes share more equally the burden of field work. Sometimes the increasing population pressure may induce the men to emigrate from the region in search of wage labour elsewhere. In this case of male depletion the women may have to take over some operations previously performed by men. Many such changes have taken place in various parts of Africa during the rapid growth of population in recent times.
Before the European conquest of Africa, felling, hunting and warfare were the chief occupations of men in the regions of female farming. Gradually, as felling and hunting became less important and inter-tribal warfare was prevented by European domination, little remained for the men to do. The Europeans, accustomed to the male farming systems of their home countries, looked with little sympathy on this unfamiliar distribution of the work load between the sexes and understandably, the concept of the ‘lazy African men’ was firmly fixed in the minds of settlers and administrators. European extension agents in many parts of Africa tried to induce the under-employed male villagers to cultivate commercial crops for export to Europe, and the system of colonial taxation by poll tax on the households was used as a means to force the Africans to produce cash crops. These were at least partly cultivated by the men, and the sex distribution of agricultural work was thus to some extent modified on the lines encouraged by the Europeans. In many other cases, however, European penetration in Africa resulted in women enlarging their part in agricultural work in the villages, because both colonial officers and white settlers recruited unmarried males for work, voluntary or forced, in road building or other heavy constructional work, in mines and on plantations.
As a result of all these changes, the present pattern of sex roles in African agriculture is more diversified than the one which gave rise to the European concept of the ‘lazy African men’. Therefore, the picture presented by Baumann’s map of the sex distribution of work for food production must be broadened and brought up to date to take into account the introduction of cash crops and the changes in the sex proportions in African villages brought about by male migrations.
The available data, although insufficient for drawing up a picture for the whole of Africa, gives very useful information about male and female work input in African farming in a number of local case studies. Sometimes these cover some hundred families selected by accepted sampling methods and representative ...

Table of contents

  1. Cover Page
  2. Title Page
  3. Copyright Page
  4. Introduction: Boserup Revisited
  5. Preface
  6. Contents
  7. Figures
  8. Tables
  9. Part I In the Village
  10. Part II In the Town
  11. Part III From Village to Town
  12. Appendix—Tables 31–46
  13. Notes to Tables and Figures
  14. List of Works Cited
  15. Author index
  16. Subject index