Punishment and Social Structure
eBook - ePub

Punishment and Social Structure

  1. 268 pages
  2. English
  3. ePUB (mobile friendly)
  4. Available on iOS & Android
eBook - ePub

Punishment and Social Structure

Book details
Book preview
Table of contents
Citations

About This Book

Why are certain methods of punishment adopted or rejected in a given social situation? To what extent is the development of penal methods determined by basic social relations? The answers to these questions are complex, and go well beyond the thesis that institutionalized punishment is simply for the protection of society. While today's punishment of offenders often incorporates aspects of psychology, psychiatry, and sociology, at one time there was a more pronounced difference in criminal punishment based on class and economics. Punishment and Social Structure originated from an article written by Georg Rusche in 1933 entitled "Labor Market and Penal Sanction: Thoughts on the Sociology of Criminal Justice." Originally published in Germany by the Frankfurt Institute of Social Research, this article became the germ of a theory of criminology that laid the groundwork for all subsequent research in this area. Rusche and Kirchheimer look at crime from an historical perspective, and correlate methods of punishment with both temporal cultural values and economic conditions. The authors classify the history of crime into three primary eras: the early Middle Ages, in which penance and fines were the predominant modes of punishment; the later Middle Ages, in which harsh corporal punishment and capital punishment moved to the forefront; and the seventeenth century, in which the prison system was more fully developed. They also discuss more recent forms of penal practice, most notably under the constraints of a fascist state.The majority of the book was translated from German into English, and then reshaped by Rusche's co-author, Otto Kirchheimer, with whom Rusche actually had little discussion. While the main body of Punishment and Social Structure are Rusche's ideas, Kirchheimer was responsible for bringing the book more up-to-date to include the Nazi and fascist era. Punishment and Social Structure is a pioneering work that sets a paradigm for the study of crime and punishment.

Frequently asked questions

Simply head over to the account section in settings and click on “Cancel Subscription” - it’s as simple as that. After you cancel, your membership will stay active for the remainder of the time you’ve paid for. Learn more here.
At the moment all of our mobile-responsive ePub books are available to download via the app. Most of our PDFs are also available to download and we're working on making the final remaining ones downloadable now. Learn more here.
Both plans give you full access to the library and all of Perlego’s features. The only differences are the price and subscription period: With the annual plan you’ll save around 30% compared to 12 months on the monthly plan.
We are an online textbook subscription service, where you can get access to an entire online library for less than the price of a single book per month. With over 1 million books across 1000+ topics, we’ve got you covered! Learn more here.
Look out for the read-aloud symbol on your next book to see if you can listen to it. The read-aloud tool reads text aloud for you, highlighting the text as it is being read. You can pause it, speed it up and slow it down. Learn more here.
Yes, you can access Punishment and Social Structure by Otto Kirchheimer in PDF and/or ePUB format, as well as other popular books in Sciences sociales & Criminologie. We have over one million books available in our catalogue for you to explore.

Information

Publisher
Routledge
Year
2017
ISBN
9781351495394
Edition
1
Subtopic
Criminologie

Notes

Notes

Chapter I

1. Georg von Mayr, Die GleichmĂ€ssigkeit im Gesellschaftsleben (MĂŒnchen, 1877); Statistik und Gesellschaftslehre, Vol. Ill, Moralstatistik mit Einschluss der Kriminalstatistik (TĂŒbingen, 1917). On Quetelet's work see R. Wassermann, Die Entwicklungsphasen der kriminalstatistischen Forschung (Leipzig, 1927), pp. 10-40.
2. L. GĂŒnther, Die Idee der Widervergeltung in der Geschichte und Philosophic des Strafrechts (3 vols.; Erlangen, 1889-95). Books like R. His, Das Strafrecht des deutschen Mittelalters (2 vols.; Leipzig and Weimar, 1920-35), which give an extraordinary exposition of the various criminal laws and regulations, but always within the categories accepted at the time of writing, are virtually useless for an examination of the relationship between systems of punishment and social order. See the pertinent criticism of E. Schmidt in his review of His in the Zeitschrift fĂŒr die gesamte Strafrechtsivissenschaft, LV (1936), 429-32.
3. See, for example, the typical study of E. Durkheim, "Deux lois de l'évolution pénale," L'Année sociologique, IV (1899-1900), 65-95.
4. R. von Ihering, Der Zweck im Recht (2d ed.; Leipzig, 1884), I, 492, says that anyone who places the social goods on one side and punishments on the other has the value-scale of society.

Chapter II

1. See the interesting remarks of Gustav Radbruch in "Stand und Strafrecht," Schweizer Zeitschrift fĂŒr Strafrecht, III (1934-35), 17-30. especially p. 19.
2. See J. Kulischer, Allgemeine Wirtschaftsgeschichte des Mittelalters und der Neuzeit (MĂŒnchen, 1928), I, 128-35; G. Schmoller, Grundriss der allgemeinen Volkswirtschaftslehre (Leipzig, 1904), II, 513; Max Weber, General Economic History, tr. by F. H. Knight (New York, 1927), pp. 132-33.
3. W. S. Holdsworth, A History of English Law (3d ed.; London, 1922-24), II, 36.
4. P. Vinogradolf, "Wergeld und Stand," Collected Papers (Oxford, 1928), II, 84-152.
5. Radbruch, op. cit.; C. R. Köstlin, Geschichte des deutschen Strafrechts im Umriss (TĂŒbingen, 1859), p. 113.
6. Art. 4 of the coutumier de Sion of the year 1338, quoted in J. Graven, Essai sur l'évolution du droit pénal valaisan (Lausanne, 1927), pp. 266-67.
7. J. Goebel, Jr., Felony and Misdemeanor, I (New York, 1937), 237.
8. Holdsworth, op. cit., Ill, 242. The same picture is revealed in a complaint mentioned in the Recess of Courten, dated Dec. 14, 1543, where it is protested that the governors impose excessive fines and legal costs on their subjects. This is easily comprehensible in view of the practice of dividing revenue under these two heads between judges and justiciaries; see Graven, op. cit., pp. 208-13.
9. A. Doren, Italienische Wirtschaftsgeschichte, I (Jena, 1934), 577, writes in this connection: "The system of fines is already at an advanced state of evolution in the direction o£ its present position in the administration of criminal law. In essence we are already far removed from the composition system of German laws. Fiscal considerations are clearly perceptible in the town and guild statutes." For the same development in England see J. C. Fox, The History of Contempt of Court, the Form of Trial and the Mode of Punishment (Oxford, 1927), p. 138; for France, R. Garraud, Traité théorique et pratique du droit pénal français (2d ed.; Paris, 1898), I, 111. Most recently, Goebel, op. cit., pp. 133, 222, 227n., 228, and 236, has emphasized the exclusively fiscal character of seignorial justice.
10. R. H. Tawney, Religion and the Rise of Capitalism (London, 1926), p. 86. In Florence in 1380, 17,000 out of a total population of about 90,000 were dependent on charity; see G. Dahm, Das Strafrecht ltaliens im ausgehenden Mittelalter (Berlin, 1931), p. 23.
11. G. von Below, Probleme der Wirtschaftsgeschichte (TĂŒbingen, 1920), p. 443.
12. F. G. Knapp, Die Bauernbefreiung und der Ursprung der Landarbeiter in den Àlteren Theilen Preussens (Leipzig, 1887), I, 43-44.
13. More, Utopia with the "Dialogue of Comfort" (London, 1928), p. 23.
14. W. Andreas, Deutsch/and vor de1· Reformation (Stuttgart, 1932), pp. 370-71.
15. G. Steinhausen, Geschichte der deutschen Kultur (3d rev. ed.; Leipzig, 1929), p. 312.
16. Andreas, op. cit., p. 289.
17. E. Frohneberg, Bevölkerungslehre und Bevölkerungspolitik des Merkantilismus (Frankfurt, 1930), p. 17.
18. J. Strieder, Zur Genesis des modernen Kapitalismus (2d ed.; MĂŒnchen, 1935), p. VIII,
19. Tawney, op. cit., p. 86. Doren, op. cit., I, 66o, takes a very similar view of the conditions prevailing in the Italian towns of this period. It is worth noting that he, too, describes the guilds as a cover and instrument for the policy of the employers. He writes that the proletariat was strangled by its inability to obtain raw materials and working instruments, by the law, and by the regulations of the guilds which admitted workers to membership with no rights whatever; the proletariat was held captive by the state, definitely a class state which acted as protector for the interests united in the large capitalist guilds; it was held down by legal restrictions on the right of association and thus prevented from improving its condition by lawful means. F. Rörig, "Die europÀische Stadt," PropylÀen Weltgeschichte, IV (Berlin, 1932), 324-26, writes similarly of the Flemish towns.
20. T. Somerlad, "Zur Geschkhte der Preise," Handwörterbuch der Staatswissenschaften, VI (4th ed.; Jena, 1925), 1037-55.
21. Schmoller, op. cit., II, 295. According to Lamprecht's calculation, the average wage of a carpenter in the years 1277-84 was 3.43 g. silver; this rose in 1344-45 to 6.84 g.; then the fall set in and by 1465 it had sunk to 3.20 g., and in 1497 stood at 2.50 g.; see Somerlad, op. cit., p. 1042.
22. E. Bielschowsky, Die sozialen und ökonomischen Grundlagen des modernen gewerblichen Schlichtungswesens und seine · Bedeutung fĂŒr die Lösung der sozialen Frage (Berlin, 1921), p. 30.
23. J. Huizinga, The Waning of the Middle Ages, tr. by F. Hopman (London, 1927), p. 21.
24. Radbruch, op. cit., p. 21.
25. Gandinus, Tractatus de maleficiis, ed. by Hermann Kantorowicz in Albertus Gandinus und das Strafrecht der Scholastik (Berlin and Leipzig, 1926), II, 347-48; cf. Dahm, op. cit., pp. 23-28; H. Gwinner, Der Einfluss des Standes im gemeinen Strafrecht (Breslau-Neukirch, 1934), pp. 18-21.
26. Clagspiegel, ed. by Sebastian Brant (Strassburg, 1538), folio 131. R. von Hippel, Deutsches Strafrecht (Berlin, 1925), I, 128-29, confirms this process which is well known to all historians of criminal law. He writes that the injured party could come to an agreement with the offender, even in the case of an offense punishable by law, by requiring him to make...

Table of contents

  1. Cover
  2. Half Title
  3. Title
  4. Copyright
  5. Contents
  6. TABLES
  7. INTRODUCTION TO THE TRANSACTION EDITION
  8. FOREWORD
  9. PREFACE
  10. I. INTRODUCTION
  11. II. SOCIAL CONDITIONS AND PENAL ADMINISTRATION IN THE LATER MIDDLE AGES
  12. III. MERCANTILISM AND THE RISE OF IMPRISONMENT
  13. IV. CHANGES IN THE FORM OF PUNISHMENT
  14. V. DEVELOPMENTS IN CRIMINAL THEORY AND LAW DURING THE AGE OF ENLIGHTENMENT
  15. VI. SOCIAL AND PENAL CONSEQUENCES OF THE INDUSTRIAL REVOLUTION
  16. VII. THE ABOLITION OF TRANSPORTATION
  17. VIII. THE FAILURE OF SOLITARY CONFINEMENT
  18. IX. MODERN PRISON REFORM AND ITS LIMITS
  19. X. THE FINE IN RECENT PENAL PRACTICE
  20. XI. NEW TRENDS IN PENAL POLICY UNDER FASCISM
  21. XII. PENAL POLICY AND CRIME RATE
  22. XIII. CONCLUSION
  23. NOTES
  24. INDEX