The Routledge Guidebook to Smith's Wealth of Nations
eBook - ePub

The Routledge Guidebook to Smith's Wealth of Nations

  1. 268 pages
  2. English
  3. ePUB (mobile friendly)
  4. Available on iOS & Android
eBook - ePub

The Routledge Guidebook to Smith's Wealth of Nations

Book details
Book preview
Table of contents
Citations

About This Book

Adam Smith (1723–1790) is famous around the world as the founding father of economics, and his ideas are regularly quoted and invoked by politicians, business leaders, economists, and philosophers. However, considering his fame, few people have actually read the whole of his magnum opus The Wealth of Nations – the first book to describe and lay out many of the concepts that are crucial to modern economic thinking. The Routledge Guidebook to Smith's Wealth of Nations provides an accessible, clear, and concise introduction to the arguments of this most notorious and influential of economic texts. The Guidebook examines:



  • the historical context of Smith's though and the background to this seminal work
  • the key arguments and ideas developed throughout The Wealth of Nations
  • the enduring legacy of Smith's work

The Routledge Guidebook to Smith's Wealth of Nations is essential reading for students of philosophy, economics, politics, and sociology who are approaching Smith's work for the first time.

Frequently asked questions

Simply head over to the account section in settings and click on “Cancel Subscription” - it’s as simple as that. After you cancel, your membership will stay active for the remainder of the time you’ve paid for. Learn more here.
At the moment all of our mobile-responsive ePub books are available to download via the app. Most of our PDFs are also available to download and we're working on making the final remaining ones downloadable now. Learn more here.
Both plans give you full access to the library and all of Perlego’s features. The only differences are the price and subscription period: With the annual plan you’ll save around 30% compared to 12 months on the monthly plan.
We are an online textbook subscription service, where you can get access to an entire online library for less than the price of a single book per month. With over 1 million books across 1000+ topics, we’ve got you covered! Learn more here.
Look out for the read-aloud symbol on your next book to see if you can listen to it. The read-aloud tool reads text aloud for you, highlighting the text as it is being read. You can pause it, speed it up and slow it down. Learn more here.
Yes, you can access The Routledge Guidebook to Smith's Wealth of Nations by Maria Pia Paganelli in PDF and/or ePUB format, as well as other popular books in Economics & Economic History. We have over one million books available in our catalogue for you to explore.

Information

Publisher
Routledge
Year
2019
ISBN
9781000733860
Edition
1

1

Adam Smith and the Scotland of his days

Adam Smith was born in Kirkcaldy, Scotland, in June 1723. His father, also Adam Smith, died before little Adam was born. His mother, Margaret Douglas, died in 1788, not long before her son Adam’s death in 1790.
Smith was educated in the parish school and was fluent in Latin and Greek. He went to the University of Glasgow where he studied moral philosophy under Francis Hutcheson; mathematics under one of the leading scholars on Euclid, Robert Simson; and natural philosophy or experimental philosophy, including astronomy, under Robert Dick, who used the most modern instruments to study Sir Isaac Newton’s new theories. He then won a Snell Scholarship to study at the University of Oxford, at Balliol College. The scholarship was intended for those who would be ordained in the Church of England and serve in the Episcopal Church in Scotland. Smith moved to Oxford where he spent several miserable years, studying mostly on his own, given that “our only business here [is] to go to prayers twice a day, and to lecture twice a week” as he wrote home (Letter to William Smith dated August 24, 1740. Correspondence, p. 1). This experience affected his view of education, as his criticisms of the endowed universities, such as Oxford, in the Wealth of Nations testified. He asked for, and managed to obtain, an exemption from taking holy orders, and went back to Scotland to live with his mother.
His first job was to offer public lectures on rhetoric in Edinburgh in 1748. They were a great success. He was paid with fees, a system that he will endorse in his analysis of education in the Wealth of Nations. His lectures were so successful that when an opening at the University of Glasgow came up, he was invited to move there. He took the Chair of Logic at the University of Glasgow in 1751 and then in 1752 that of Moral Philosophy. He taught Jurisprudence as well as Moral Philosophy. He continued his career as an administrator and was in charge of new acquisitions for the library. In his correspondence, he described his days at Glasgow as the happiest and best of his life.
In 1759, he published his first book, which turned out to be a best seller: The Theory of Moral Sentiments. Smith kept working on it throughout his life, with five additional editions, the last one of which came out soon before his death in 1790.
His success as a teacher and as a scholar was such that he was hired to be the private tutor of the Duke of Buccleuch, a great landowner in Scotland. As was then the custom, he accompanied the young duke on a Grand Tour of Europe. Smith and the duke left for the continent and spent time in France and Switzerland where they met many of the intellectual and aristocratic elite, including the leading economists of the time: the physiocrats. But Smith was bored in France. So he started to write the book that eventually became The Wealth of Nations. Because the brother of the young duke got sick and died, the Grand Tour had to be cut short, and Smith and his pupil went back to Scotland. Smith received a very generous pension as a compensation for his tutoring services, as well as a lifelong friendship with the duke and his family.
Back in Scotland, Smith moved back in with his beloved mother in Kirkcaldy and continued his writing of the Wealth of Nations. Being a meticulous writer, Smith took his time in finishing the book. So much so that both his publisher and his friends kept putting pressure on him to deliver the manuscript. The first printing of the Wealth of Nations dated March 1776. Given increasing tensions with the North American colonies, which culminated in the declaration of independence in July of that same year, everybody had their eyes on Smith, eager to read his thoughts on the health of the British Empire.
This book was also an immediate best seller. The 3,500 copies of the first print run sold out immediately. It went through five editions during Smith’s life and it has been in print ever since. It was translated into German the very same year as its British publication; into French and Italian within three years; and by the beginning of the new century it was also in print in Portuguese, Spanish, Danish, and Russian. The Wealth of Nations was also cited in British Parliamentary discussions on several occasions – 37 times between 1773 and 1800 alone, to be precise. Napoleon allegedly took it with him when he was sent into exile in Saint Helena. After Smith’s death, it was the book from which everyone learned economics.
Despite his pension and royalties from the two books, which alone would have provided for a comfortable life, Smith and his mother moved to Edinburgh in 1777 so he could start working as a Customs Commissioner. He took his job so seriously that he told a friend never to read the actual trade restrictions Scotland had, or he would find himself in violation of most of them. Smith did: he read the trade restrictions and found himself in violation of most of them. To set a good example, he burnt all that he was not supposed to have: most of his wardrobe!
He lived in Edinburgh until he died on July 17, 1790. He asked his executors, the chemist Joseph Black (1728–1799) and the geologist James Hutton (1726–1797), to burn all his manuscripts, at least 18 volumes. But because he did not believe they would really do it, he ended up doing it himself a few days before he died. Possibly in those pages there was also a third book, on the theory of jurisprudence, which he promised in the last paragraph of the first edition of The Theory of Moral Sentiments, and which he claimed to be still working on in the advertisement of the last edition of The Theory of Moral Sentiments. While we were able to have copies of the notes of his lectures on jurisprudence because two sets of students’ notes have been discovered, one in 1890s and one in 1958, there is still no trace of a surviving copy of this third book, which most likely would have been based on those jurisprudence lectures.
The house he owned in Edinburgh, now property of the Edinburgh Business School and a center for the promotion of Adam Smith’s legacy, was used for his extensive entertaining. Smith hosted dinners for famous visitors to Edinburgh and some of the many clubs he belonged to, as well as a regular Sunday evening dinner for friends.

The Scottish economy

The clubs and societies Smith belonged to were typical of the time in which he lived. Clubs were groups of intellectuals who met on a regular basis to discuss topics of interests and recent scientific discoveries. France had an equivalent in the form of salons. But differently from France, where ladies attended and sometimes hosted the salons, Scottish clubs were all male. Participants came from all walks of life: they included businessmen, chemists, botanists, poets, astronomers, physicians, physicists, clergymen, lawyers, moral philosophers, inventors, geologists, architects, academics, and bureaucrats. Almost all intellectuals now associated with the Scottish Enlightenment belonged to some of these clubs.
The intellectual excitement of eighteenth-century Scotland took place in a small developing country growing at a very fast rate. Since the Union with England in 1707 and the formation of Great Britain, Scotland may have lost its political independence, but it gained access to large overseas markets, including the English colonies. The colonial trade was now fully available to Scottish merchants and Scottish ports. The total tonnage of oceanic vessels passing through Scotland ports rose from 54,407 in 1759 to 109,895 tons in 1771, and costal vessels from 150,995 to 257,494. Glasgow soon became the largest port for tobacco trade in the world. Scottish linen manufacturing ballooned. Iron manufacturing and coal output increased by more than a factor of 10. Sugar refining, rope and sailcloth manufacturing, tanning, kelp and soap production, and fishery, all experienced very rapid growth. Agricultural production improved too, driven by high demand. In few decades, the price of Highland cattle tripled.
This rapid and significant growth required and was sustained through investment in infrastructure: dikes and fen draining, roads, harbors, bridges, canals, including the construction of the Forth and Clyde Canal connecting the two coasts of Scotland, and the Monklands canal linking Glasgow to the coalfields of Coatbridge. Scotland developed an extremely competitive and sophisticated banking system able to finance all these activities and to provide the financial stability needed during this rapid growth. Scotland went from being a peripheral country to a commercial and intellectual center.

Scottish politics

The 1707 Union with England opened Scotland to new markets but also caused some tensions. Especially in the Highlands of Scotland, there was still support for the dethroned Stuart monarchy. This led to armed rebellions aiming at restoring the crown to the Stuarts. The most formidable of these rebellions was in 1745, while Adam Smith was at Oxford. Charles Edward Stuart, nicknamed “Bonnie Prince Charlie”, and his Jacobite militia marched without much resistance into England to remove the Hanoverian “usurper” George II. They got as far as Derby – 130 miles from London. They then retreated into Scotland followed by the Hanoverian armies. The complete defeat of the Highlanders eventually took place in Culloden, in the Highlands, on April 16, 1746.
This episode was embarrassing for some Scots, including Adam Smith, who was made fun of because of his Scottish origins by his English classmates at Oxford. Scotland was considered a backward country, far from the more developed and “superior” England, inhabited with, in the words of David Hume – another prominent Scottish philosopher and eventually Smith’s best friend, – “bare-arsed Highlanders”. But this rebellion was also a warning that a few thousand of those “naked unarmed Highlanders” (in Smith’s words this time) could arrive unscathed at the door of the capital of the largest empire in the world – a concern that Smith would generalize in his treatment of national defense in the Wealth of Nations.
To prevent further insurrection, in part under the pretext of, or simply in conjunction with, agricultural reforms, the clan system in the Highland was outlawed and many forced to leave their land, either to the lowlands or to the colonies: the so-called Highland Clearances. The feudal power of life and death of Highland chiefs was abolished in 1746, weapons were forbidden, and the tartan outlawed. The chiefs could no longer have private armies, thus finding it more profitable to use their land for sheep.
There were thus two Scotlands until after Culloden: the prosperous, Anglophone Lowland corridor from Glasgow to Edinburgh, Whig in politics and Protestant in religion; and the tribal, Gaelic-speaking Highlands far from government and the rule of law, a “no-go” area for peaceable Lowlanders; Tory in politics and either Catholic or Episcopalian in religion; which the Enlightened Scots wanted to “improve”.

The Highlands and the stages of development

The relationship between Scotland and its Highlands remained ambiguous. On the one hand, the Highlands represented a backward part of the country, especially compared to the booming Lowlands. On the other hand, it represented a set of admirable values to contrast against the corruptions that this fast economic growth was bringing.
All this trade Scotland was experiencing was transforming Lowland Scotland into a commercial society. A commercial society differed from other kinds of societies: hunter-gatherer, pastoral, and agricultural. The common belief was that each kind of society had its own set of values; its material conditions and material incentives; and its legal, political, social, and moral characteristics. Hunter-gatherers were “savages”, with little property and little government. Women were subjected to men, there was slavery, and age and physical strength were marks of distinction. Shepherds were “barbarians” who began to recognize property, but only in a limited way. Tribal chiefs ruled with personal power and justice was generally arbitrary. Property in land developed with agricultural societies and with it chivalry too. These were “civilized” societies. “Civilized” meant urban, organized in urban communities – from the Latin civis, or city. Commercial societies were the apex of “refinement” and “politeness”. Here we see fully developed courts and legal systems, and evolved forms of government that rely on impersonal rule of law. Opulence was, therefore, linked with good governance, the presence of the rule of law, and of a good administration of justice. The Scottish thinkers generally believed that commerce and thus commercial societies brought about the “two greatest blessings that man can possess” – “opulence and freedom” (LJ p. 185) – not just for a few but for all.
Note that the language used here, inappropriate by today’s standards, was not meant to be offensive at the time. These are all specific terms of art to indicate specific characteristics of different kinds of societies. Civil is in contrast to rude, as opposed to, say, the contemporary Swiss philosopher Jean-Jacques Rousseau who would contrast civil with natural. The rudeness of the savage hunter-gatherer and barbaric nomadic shepherd is contrasted to the civilized agricultural and refined commercial society in a way that is mostly descriptive rather than judgmental.
Associated with these different stages of development, the Scots observed and appreciated different virtues. Agricultural societies valued stability and “masculine” virtues. The enlargement of society, which commerce brought about, implied increasing interactions with others, and with the other sex as well, which induced people to be more sociable and more likely to develop sociable virtues. Historical development was perceived as a process of civilization and “feminization”. Societies developed from rude savagery and barbarism, from masculine stages, where aggression, strength, and courage are valued, to more civil and feminine stages, where sociability, kindness, and desire to emulate are valued – to a world of conversation and commerce.
Feminization could slip into “effeminacy”, though. While feminization is generally a positive thing for the Scots, effeminacy is not. This was a derogatory term. Effeminacy was dangerous and reproachable. Commercial societies, with their wealth and luxuries, more than any other kinds of society, may lead to effeminacy, potentially distracting individuals from the public sphere and weakening the traditional masculine virtues. Andrew Fletcher of Saltoun (1655–1716), Adam Ferguson (1723–1816), and Robert Wallace (1697–1771), in particular, saw the cost of the increased sociability as a decrease in martial spirit that could become a problem if the country needed to be defended. This was an issue that Adam Smith also understood, though he developed his own response to it.
Agriculture and agricultural values were seen as counter to this commercial laxity. Home gardening was promoted and became fashionable at this time: a small piece of land to cultivate in an urban or semi-urban environment was a way to mitigate the effeminacy tendencies of commerce and to keep alive the more masculine virtues of agricultural societies.
James Macpherson (1736–1796) claimed to have collected oral Gaelic stories of ancient origins and then translated them for publication. Many doubted the authenticity of Macpherson’s account, attributing the entirety of the poems to him. Nevertheless his “translation” of Ossian’s poetry between 1760 and 1763 solidified the ideals of traditional agricultural values of sobriety, as opposed to commercial laxity, and the martial spirit of the Highlanders.
The Caledonians, the local Gaelic-speaking Celtic tribes of the Highlands, became an idealized type that was able to combine the politeness and civility of a commercial society, in which there is no slavery and women are treated with respect and gallantry, with agricultural values of martial masculinity.
The reception of this image of Scotland was not always successful, especially among its southern neighbors, but it became influential in Europe, especially Germany, sowing the seeds of what would become the Romantic movement.

Improvements and enlightenment

The booming economic growth and the booming intellectual life were linked with an “ideology of improvement” and experimentation. A large variety of experiments were tried with a large variance in their success rates, especially in agriculture. For example, spade husbandry and potato cultivation were introduced and were immediate successes. There were attempts to introduce different kinds of sheep to develop sheep farming, the success of which was evident after 1790s. Th...

Table of contents

  1. Cover
  2. Half Title
  3. Title Page
  4. Copyright Page
  5. Dedication
  6. Contents
  7. Acknowledgments
  8. 1 Adam Smith and the Scotland of his days
  9. 2 Introduction and Book I, Chapters I–III
  10. 3 Book I, Chapters IV–VII
  11. 4 Book I, Chapters VII–X
  12. 5 Book I, Chapter XI
  13. 6 Book II
  14. 7 Book III
  15. 8 Book IV, Chapters I–VI
  16. 9 Book IV, Chapters VII–IX
  17. 10 Book V, Chapter I
  18. 11 Book V, Chapters II–III
  19. 12 Legacy
  20. Index