The Planning Game
eBook - ePub

The Planning Game

An Information Economics Approach to Understanding Urban and Environmental Management

  1. 208 pages
  2. English
  3. ePUB (mobile friendly)
  4. Available on iOS & Android
eBook - ePub

The Planning Game

An Information Economics Approach to Understanding Urban and Environmental Management

Book details
Book preview
Table of contents
Citations

About This Book

Trading information is an essential aspect of the negotiations that underpin planning practice across the globe. In this book, Alex Lord uses information economics to outline a way of thinking about these negotiations that places the strategies that actors in the planning game use at the heart of the debate.

Dialogue between economics and planning theorists has been, until now, rare. Lord argues that information economics' tool kit, game theory – including well-known examples such as the Prisoners' Dilemma, the Stag Hunt game and Follow the Leader – offers an analytical framework ideally suited to unpacking planning processes.

This use of game theory to understand how counterparties interact draws together two distinct bodies of literature: firstly the mainstream economics treatment of games in abstract form and, secondly, accounts of actual bargaining in planning practice from a host of international empirical studies.

Providing a novel alternative to existing theories of planning, The Planning Game provides an explanation of how agencies interact in shaping the trajectory of development through the application of game theory to planning practice.

Frequently asked questions

Simply head over to the account section in settings and click on “Cancel Subscription” - it’s as simple as that. After you cancel, your membership will stay active for the remainder of the time you’ve paid for. Learn more here.
At the moment all of our mobile-responsive ePub books are available to download via the app. Most of our PDFs are also available to download and we're working on making the final remaining ones downloadable now. Learn more here.
Both plans give you full access to the library and all of Perlego’s features. The only differences are the price and subscription period: With the annual plan you’ll save around 30% compared to 12 months on the monthly plan.
We are an online textbook subscription service, where you can get access to an entire online library for less than the price of a single book per month. With over 1 million books across 1000+ topics, we’ve got you covered! Learn more here.
Look out for the read-aloud symbol on your next book to see if you can listen to it. The read-aloud tool reads text aloud for you, highlighting the text as it is being read. You can pause it, speed it up and slow it down. Learn more here.
Yes, you can access The Planning Game by Alex Lord in PDF and/or ePUB format, as well as other popular books in Architecture & Urban Planning & Landscaping. We have over one million books available in our catalogue for you to explore.

Information

Publisher
Routledge
Year
2012
ISBN
9781136462573
Part I

1

Planning in the ‘information age’

If, as was argued in the Introduction, information is the most valuable commodity in the conduct of environmental planning, our next questions must surely be: how do we determine what information is ‘legitimate’ in arriving at planning decisions?; and how might that information then be gathered and subsequently converted into knowledge? The first issue – how widely we interpret what constitutes ‘legitimate’ information – is of critical significance for environmental planning for several reasons. First, it exposes a clear divide between the two principal academic ways of thinking about planning practice. Indeed, their varying attitude to what types of information might be appropriate with which to furnish planning practice has often been understood to be the core distinction between planning theories derived from an almost unreconstituted Comtian positivism and an inherently normative version drawn from Habermasian sociology. Second, for a discipline such as environmental planning, with a close association to a world of professional practice, the likely correspondence between the quality of policy outcomes and the quality of the information used in the decision-making process makes the question of what types of data are held to be admissible the most fundamental question. Finally, it forces us to confront epistemological questions about how we derive knowledge from information – for example, how do we translate environmental impact studies or community consultation exercises into knowledge? This prompts us to consider what sources of data might exist and how the data that is collected is used to devise an evidence base for planning practice.
In beginning to address these questions this chapter is principally concerned with setting them in historical context, considering the development of planning theory from its first modern expression in the early part of the twentieth century through to the beginning of more recent post-positivist developments such as communicative theory, which will be the subject of Chapter 2. In taking this chronological focus the purpose is to consider the enduring influence of the positivist rationalist school, particularly on practice, and of the Habermasian sociologists, especially on theory, before diagnosing the potential epistemological shortcomings with both, and proffering an alternative, in Chapter 3.

Planning, information and evidence-based policy

The potential for public policy to be influenced by information, particularly scientific research, stretches back to the Enlightenment (Sanderson, 2003) and, more distantly, to the ‘Philosopher Kings’ of Plato’s Republic (Lee and Lee translation, 2003). Its more recent history has been understood as coinciding with the early–mid-twentieth-century heyday of modernism (for a review, see Nutley et al., 2002; see also Lasswell, 1951; Lindblom, 1959). In environmental planning this is perhaps best dated, following Hall and Tewdwr-Jones (2010: 6) to, approximately, the period 1920–60 and understood as exemplified in the work of Geddes; in particular the identification of the ‘survey-analysis-plan’ approach, which has been understood as entirely consonant with the principles of high modernism’s faith in progress through science (Faludi and Waterhout, 2006a). Such is the standing of Geddes as the forefather of urban and environmental planning that there now exists a vast corpus of work, both biographical and analytical, devoted to cataloguing the methods of planning advocated in his writings, all of which emphasise his role in transforming planning into a ‘scientific’ endeavour, as Dehaene (2002: 48) argues:
Discussions about survey in urbanism introduced models of scientific thinking into a profession which was still dominated by architects. The introduction of scientific methods was believed to grant the profession greater authority, and expanded the scope of its activities. On the surface, the introduction of scientific methods seems to constitute a radical redefinition of urbanism, turning it overnight from a liberal art into a positive science.
Critically this revolution, here portrayed as the transition of planning from art to science, was perhaps more complex. For Geddes the ‘science’ of the survey in generating fine-grained information about the nature of the place for which a plan was being prepared was understood to be a necessary, but preliminary, stage upon which the subsequent art and design of planning as an outgrowth of architecture were incumbent. This idea of science first, art later can be seen in much of Geddes’s work, where ‘information’, understood as the quasi-scientific modelling of human kind’s relationship with the urban and natural environments, is constructed as precursor to imagining the possible:
The corresponding constructive endeavour is now no mere School of traditional learning or of useful information. It is one of science in a new and reorganised sense; one of philosophy also, one of ideals above all … The mere observations of the senses and their records in memory become transformed into the images of the poet, the imagery too of the artist, for art proper is only thus born.
(Geddes, 1905: 59)
For many authors the planning that this approach spawned went on to become the dominant paradigm for both the theory and practice of urban and environmental management throughout the middle years of the twentieth century (for a review, see Muller, 1992). Moreover in the 1960s and 1970s the continued trajectory of this conception of planning, rooted in an a priori judgement about what types of information are of most use to the planner, can be seen in the subsequent development of the ‘rational’ (see Meyerson and Banfield, 1955; Faludi, 1973) and ‘systems’ (see McLoughlin, 1969) theories of planning. Whilst recasting the activity as a goal-orientated, problem-solving exercise, echoing the ‘management by objectives’ literature popular at the time, to some extent distinguishes these theories from Geddes’s conception of planning as well-informed creativity, in other respects the parallels between earlier and later positivist theories are significant. For example both incarnations draw on pseudo-scientific analogy: evolutionary biology in the case of Geddes (Muller, 1992) and cybernetics in systems theory (McLoughlin, 1969) and, to a lesser extent, in the rationalist school of thought (Thomas, 1979). In the case of Faludi (1973: 25), responsible for the seminal articulation of the comprehensive/procedural-rationalist conception of planning, this supports an understanding of planning that echoes strongly that of Geddes, based upon the ‘rational process of thought and action which ultimately aims (as science does) at promoting human growth’. As this notion of rationality carries with it a compulsion to base decision-making processes on reason, it follows that information is no less central to fulfilling the positivist epistemological requirements of this theory than that of the survey-before-plan approach of Geddes.
With information of this quasi-scientific nature understood to form the orthodox basis of planning in many contexts by the 1970s (or in some cases before), the subsequent years, it might be argued, have not seen a significant diminution in the reification of positivist data, particularly amongst policy makers. The emergence in the 1980s of tools such as Geographical Information Systems software has paved the way for more refined geodemographic analyses and the construction of more detailed indicators, models, forecasts, projections and geographically weighted regressions (Brunsdon and Fotheringham, 1996), the reliability of which is fundamentally dependent on the quality of the data upon which they are predicated. The result is that by the 1990s the use of quantitative indicators and metrics had become a staple part of planning practice around the globe. Indeed, as the computational tools at the disposal of the planning profession have become ever more sophisticated it is clear that, by the new century, information and communications technologies have come to play an increasingly prominent role in how planning policy is designed and implemented. The dawn of a mass-communication ‘information age’ makes this a role forecast to grow, not diminish (Drummond and French, 2008).
Understanding the longevity and persistence of this trend is accomplished by reference to a wider movement in public administration that emphasises the desirability for policy to be unequivocally based on ostensibly apolitical, objective evidence. This has been particularly relevant in planning where the value of impartial evidence might be twofold: first, to legitimise policy choices as consistent with an objective construction of the ‘public interest’ and, second, to quell the controversy that would accompany a more conspicuously political decision-making process. The resultant conception of planning as part of a public sector designed to collect and respond to information has given rise to a vast corpus of academic literature that has variously understood this type of evidence-based policy as either a progressive activity associated with the New Public Management movement (Newman, 2001; Nutley and Davies, 2000; Nutley et al., 2000; Pawson, 2002a, 2002b) or else the elision of independent research with policy activism (Bridges, 1998; Harris, 2002; Solesbury, 2001). In addition, for some, the political impulse behind this drive to connect policy with evidence has been understood as part of a ‘post-ideological’ (Painter and Clarence, 2001: 1215) strain in the progressive movements that dominated politics in those nation states where evidence-based policy has enjoyed most prominence since the 1990s: Clinton’s Democrats, Die Neue Mitte in Merkel’s Germany and the New Labour project of Blair and Brown. On this account, the idea that policy could be led by evidence rather than conviction has been neatly summarised by the aphorism, ‘what matters is what works’ (Southern, 2001: 264; see also Davies et al., 2000; Perri 6, 2002).
Extending this line of thought, others (Newman, 2001; Stoker, 1999) have seen evidence-based policy as inextricably bound up with the transition from government to governance (for instance, Rhodes, 1997). The erosion of state power by the forces of trans-national economic organisation, it is argued, necessitates organs of the state at all territorial scales to recognise the multiplicity of stakeholders with a de facto involvement in the design and delivery of policy and so forge partnerships that acknowledge and mirror this diversity (Pawson, 2006). Across the globe in areas as wide ranging as education policy (Pirrie, 2001; Simons et al., 2003), healthcare (El Ansari et al., 2001), social work (Humphries, 2003) and urban policy (Dobbs and Moore, 2002) the necessity for evidence to instil a shared purpose and sense of coherency by which partnership-based governance might be sustained has been identified (see Young et al., 2002). For instance Nutley et al., (2002: 4; see also Laycock, 2000; Nutley et al., 2000) advise that:
gaining consensus or even widespread agreement will not be easy. The need to secure some common ground between diverse stakeholders does, however, point the way to more positive approaches. The traditional separation between the policy arena, practitioners communities and the research community has largely proven unhelpful. Much of the more recent thinking in this area now emphasises the need for partnerships if common ground is to be found.
This logic is easy to see: if policy – such as that in urban and environmental management – is to be made and implemented by complex networks of actors, some public, some private, some hybrid, some third sector, it follows that a binding rationale for action is essential to realise coherency and coordination. More simply, as Powell and Moon (2001: 48) argue, what is required for this style of governance to work is ‘an evidence base for partnership’.

Making evidence count

In addition to the argument that evidence binds together the partnerships needed to devise and deliver joined-up policy, an alternative view has emphasised a loss of public confidence in political process, politicians and policy makers across the globe as explaining the move towards public policy supported by ostensibly impartial, objective evidence (Norris, 1999; Stoker, 2010). If decisions can be made that rely purely on hard facts, political wilfulness and bias might be nullified, so the argument goes. When added to the simultaneous austerity in public finances encountered in many states following the international financial crisis of 2007 onwards, this perhaps explains increased scrutiny of public spending on activities such as urban regeneration and regulatory practices like environmental planning and a corresponding demand to justify decisions on the grounds of being ‘useful’ and ‘relevant’ (Solesbury, 2002). But what is useful or relevant is itself an inherently subjective matter.
With respect to environmental planning this throws into sharp relief the issue of normative information. Whilst it is clear that planning might need to take into account positivist research across a whole range of areas – geodemographic change, environmental assessments of various types, transport patterns, changes in the demand for different types of housing, to name only a few – much of the daily work of a planner (Healey, 1992a) is concerned with weighing judgements. Sometimes this might be testimonies, for example, about the aesthetic value of historic built environments and the quality of life implications of access to green space; these are important issues that are not easily captured by the positivist framework. However, they might equally well be subjective interpretations of what is ostensibly objective data. Just as in all aspects of the social sciences where the variables under consideration are inherently complex, deciphering a coherent evidence base when confronted by information of such differing types is inevitably fraught with difficulty (Martin and Sanderson, 1999).
It is from this perspective that many have come to criticise the positivist conception of what counts as information. Specific to environmental planning, in commenting on the work of Taylor (1980), Faludi (1986: 38) describes the approach pioneered by Geddes as informed by a ‘crudely positivist view of scientific method’, an assessment echoed by McLoughlin’s (1969: 125) critique that the rationalist approach is pregnant with the ‘tendency towards collecting information for its own sake, unselective and uncritical wallowing in facts and figures’. Sharing this perspective, the first articulations of communicative planning theory in the 1980s (Forester, 1980, 1989) date the beginnings of a post-positivist wave of planning theory that has ever since urged academics and practitioners alike to take normative information seriously and ensure that plans respond effectively to the subjective aspirations and preferences of communities. For such communicative theorists the information derived from the testimonies of residents and representative groups is just as vital in framing good planning policy as that of experts. In short, the opinions of the people who have to live with planning decisions should feature at least as prominently in the policy- and decision-making processes as the bureaucrat’s understanding of what constitutes the public interest, premised frequently on technical analyses conducted at city hall, remote from the site of any intervention.
The effects of this agenda on practice have been profound. For example, in reflecting on these ideas Nadin (2006: 21; see also Box 5.1, Chapter 5 of this volume), using the example of the English system of planning, urges a reconsideration of the types of information that might be useful to planners. In identifying connections that run between different types of information within an evidence base, the author suggests something much more expansive than the narrow definition of information identified by the positivist nexus in planning thought:
The finding that responses from community consultation are sometimes referred to as ‘evidence’ deserves further comment. Material arising from community and stakeholder engagement is different from what is indicated in PPS12 [Planning Policy Statement 12] as ‘evidence’ …. Its use in developing and evaluating alternatives and as part of the justification of choices that are made is normal and appropriate however. The material that emerges from the engagement of stakeholders and the community can add real knowledge about the place and the community, because of the authoritative bodies involved and because of the familiarity with the area.
… There is a reciprocal relationship between other types of evidence and community responses however. Information provided to those engaging in the process – through the issues and options consultation stage for instance – enables people to understand better what the local development framework is seeking to do or needs to do. This enables them to make informed representations that are likely to be more useful to the local planning authority, or more effective in influencing the emerging plan.
The underlying theme is a distinction between information derived from research of a positivist nature – housing and labour market studies, environmental impact assessment and habitats regulations – and that gathered through the participation of stakeholders and communities in consultation processes. On this account best practice for planners is constructed as gathering a wide range of information that can be attuned to local circumstances through community participation. To reinforce this point Nadin (2006: 21) concludes that:
A wide and inclusive view needs to be taken of what constitutes evidence. Anything which assists in understanding ...

Table of contents

  1. Cover
  2. Title
  3. Copyright
  4. Contents
  5. Text boxes and figures
  6. Introduction
  7. Part I
  8. Part II
  9. References
  10. Index