The Islamic Law on Land Tax and Rent
eBook - ePub

The Islamic Law on Land Tax and Rent

The Peasants' Loss of Property Rights as Interpreted in the Hanafite Legal Literature of the Mamluk and Ottoman Periods

  1. 152 pages
  2. English
  3. ePUB (mobile friendly)
  4. Available on iOS & Android
eBook - ePub

The Islamic Law on Land Tax and Rent

The Peasants' Loss of Property Rights as Interpreted in the Hanafite Legal Literature of the Mamluk and Ottoman Periods

Book details
Book preview
Table of contents
Citations

About This Book

This book, first published in 1988, argues that a close inspection of the development of Hanafite law in the Mamluk and Ottoman periods reveals changes in legal doctrine which were not restricted to civil transactions but also concerned the public law. It focuses in particular on the interrelated areas of property, rent and taxation of arable lands, arguing that changes in the relationship between tax and rent led to a redefinition of the concept of landed property, a concept at the very heart of the Islamic legal system. This title will be of particular interest to students of Islamic history.

Frequently asked questions

Simply head over to the account section in settings and click on “Cancel Subscription” - it’s as simple as that. After you cancel, your membership will stay active for the remainder of the time you’ve paid for. Learn more here.
At the moment all of our mobile-responsive ePub books are available to download via the app. Most of our PDFs are also available to download and we're working on making the final remaining ones downloadable now. Learn more here.
Both plans give you full access to the library and all of Perlego’s features. The only differences are the price and subscription period: With the annual plan you’ll save around 30% compared to 12 months on the monthly plan.
We are an online textbook subscription service, where you can get access to an entire online library for less than the price of a single book per month. With over 1 million books across 1000+ topics, we’ve got you covered! Learn more here.
Look out for the read-aloud symbol on your next book to see if you can listen to it. The read-aloud tool reads text aloud for you, highlighting the text as it is being read. You can pause it, speed it up and slow it down. Learn more here.
Yes, you can access The Islamic Law on Land Tax and Rent by Baber Johansen in PDF and/or ePUB format, as well as other popular books in Theology & Religion & Religion. We have over one million books available in our catalogue for you to explore.

Information

Publisher
Routledge
Year
2016
ISBN
9781315312590
Edition
1
Subtopic
Religion

1
The Birth of the Kharāj Payer

1. What is Kharāj?

The basic legal principle that governs the ` position on taxation is summarised in the following sentence ascribed to Abū Ḥanīfa:
In contrast to all other commodities, the productive lands in our territory are never exempted from taxation. This taxation consists either of kharāj or of ʿushr (al-arāḍi n-nāmiyatu lā takhlū ʿan waẓīfat in fī dārinā wa-l-waẓīfat" imma l-kharāju awi l-ʿushr).1
Whereas European feudalism recognised the maxim 'Nulle terre sans seigneur', the Hanafite jurists adhered to the principle 'Nulle terre sans taxe'.2 The right of the state to tax all landed property was never questioned by the Hanafite jurists. It is, therefore, not coincidental that the first known Hanafite book of law is Abū Yūsuf's Kitāb al-kharāj, the 'Book on the Landtax'. Hanafite jurists recognised only two legitimate forms of taxes to be levied on landed property: ʿushr and kharāj. It is well known and generally acknowledged that ʿushr is a tax on the landed property of Muslims. What is not well known and certainly not generally acknowledged by scholars is that according to Hanafite law not only ʿushr but also kharāj are taxes payable by the proprietors of landed property. It is difficult to explain why this aspect of kharāj as a tax on private landed property is not generally acknowledged by Western scholars. For nearly 200 years, specialists in the field have tried to draw attention to the fact that kharāj is a tax payable by the private proprietor of landed property. Some 170 years ago, von Hammer was the first to draw attention to this fact.3 He was followed by Belin in the second half of the nineteenth century.4 Seventy years ago, Aghnides clearly stated that kharāj proves ownership of property in Hanafite law,5 a fact of which Gibb and Bowen reminded us some 20 years ago.6 European historians, especially those concerned with the economic and social history of the Near and the Middle East, do not seem to accept this point of view. Even outstanding scholars such as Becker7 and, in his earlier works, Claude Cahen8 state that the Islamic law defines kharāj as a tax the payment of which implies acknowledging state-held title of ownership to the lands concerned.9 This is not the position of the Hanafites, although it is held by other Sunnī schools of Islamic law. Western scholars have often been confused by the divergence of legal opinions on this question, as they tend to underestimate the differences between the Sunnī schools of law. Some scholars, therefore, simply pass over certain information in the Hanafite texts that they study. Some years ago, Paul Forand, in his essay on the Sawād lands of Iraq, drew extensively on the work of an early Hanafite jurist in order to describe the juridical status of the inhabitants of the Sawād lands without indicating that the jurist whom he quotes unequivocally states that the lands of the Sawād are the property of their owners if they pay kharāj on them.10 Other Western scholars try to reconcile the Orientalist understanding of Islamic law with their Hanafite texts. In a recently published important study on the pre-Islamic traditions relating to agriculture in Iraq and their influence on the Muslim reorganisation of the relations of production in agriculture, Morony points out that the Hanafite jurist Sarakhsī considers kharāj lands as the private property of the tax payers. Morony then adds that with regard to kharāj 'in fact al-Shāfiʿī's interpretation was preferred by the legal scholars thus contributing to the van Berchem thesis ...'11 This holds true for Western scholars. Hanafite jurists continued to prefer the tradition of their own school.
For the argument I shall develop in this essay, it is important to provide an accurate description of the Hanafite legal position on kharāj by presenting statements on this question by authoritative eighth- to nineteenth-century Hanafite scholars. Abū Yūsuf, writing in the eighth century, declares that land assigned through iqāāʿ becomes the private property of the assignee who has to pay kharāj12 and that kharāj also has to be paid on reclaimed mawāt lands, since, in this case, the cultivator becomes the proprietor. The fact that in this case the cultivator and proprietor has to pay kharāj13 shows that private property is subject to kharāj. The rule that in a contract of share-cropping (muzāraʿa) the proprietor is required to pay kharāj14 would indicate the same. Abū Yūsufs companion, Shaibānī, declared it licit for Muslims to buy kharāj lands from non- Muslim subjects of the Muslim government,15 even for strictly commercial purposes.16 These legal opinions of early Hanafite jurists are not whimsical juridical abstractions. In his penetrating analysis of the development of the theory of faiʾ, Schmucker points out that not only were there legal opinions to this effect but these legal traditions reflected the historical practice of private appropriation of kharāj lands in Iraq.17 According to Schmucker, the Sawād lands of Iraq were left in the hands of the inhabitants of the Sawād who could freely dispose of them. Only crown lands (ṣawāfī) fell under immediate state control.18 The Hanafite legal position on kharāj supports the ensuing rights of the owners of kharāj lands. In the ninth century, the Hanafite jurist, Khaṣṣāf, writing in Iraq, sanctioned the transformation of kharāj lands into waqf on the grounds that 'the lands of kharāj belong to their proprietors' (li-anna arḍa l-kharāji li-mālikīhā).19 In another context he states, 'It is kharāj land and is owned by those who hold it' (wa-hiya arḍu kharājin wa-hiya milkun li-arbābihā).20 In a similar vein, the Egyptian-born jurist Ṭaḥāwi explained at the beginning of the tenth century: 'The kharāj lands are private property. Their sale and donation is permissible, so is their transformation into waqf. The rules of inheritance apply to them as to all other goods' (wa-araḍu l-kharāji mamlūkātun yajūzu baiʿ uhunna wahibatuhunna wa-waqfuhunna yajrī fīha l-mawārīthu kamā yajrī fīmā siwāhurtna).21 At the beginning of the eleventh century the Iraqi author, Qudūrī, stated: 'The lands of the Sawād are the property of their inhabitants who may sell them and dispose of them [as they wish]' (wa-arḍu s-sawādi mamlūkatun li-ahlihā: yajūzi baiʿ uhum lahā wa-taṣarrufuhum fīhā).22 The eleventh-century Transoxanian author, Sarakhsī, reported that the companions of the Prophet paid kharāj. He concluded from this that the payment of kharāj cannot be regarded as a humiliation for a Muslim. After explaining the procedure for the levying of kharāj, he says the buyer of kharāj lands will have to pay the kharāj on them.23 Sarakhsī makes it clear that kharāj has one basic characteristic in common with the rent, i.e. that it is paid as a requital for the fact that it lies within the cultivator's power to put the land to use. 'The kharāj', he says, 'falls due in consideration of [the fact that] it is possible to put [his land] to use'.24 But he also makes it clear that the obligation of paying the kharāj arises only for the owner of landed property: 'The reason for which kharāj falls due is the [existence of] private property of the land that is put to use'.25 The twelfth-century Transoxanian author Marghīnānī declared that the lands of the Sawād of Iraq and those of Syria (Shām) are kharāj lands and that they are the property of their owners.26 He is supported in this legal opinion by the fifteenth-century commentator of his work, the Egyptian jurist, Ibn al-Humām.27 Continuing the same legal tradition the sixteenth-century Egyptian mufti, Ibn Nujaim, states: 'The Hanafite Imams, may God have mercy on them, are unanimously of the opinion that if the Imam conquers a country and recognises its inhabitants' rights [as proprietors] to it and imposes the kharāj on its lands, then the inhabitants enjoy the right of private property with regard to the lands. All forms by which they dispose [of them] such as sale, donation, testamentary bequest, leasing, lending and transformation into waqf are valid, regardless of whether the disposing person remains an unbeliever or becomes a Muslim' (thumma ttafaqa aʾ immatu l-Ḥanafīyati, raḥima llāhu ʿanhum, ʿalā anna l-imāma idhā fataḥa baladatan wa-aqarra ahlaha ʿalaihā wa-waḍaʿ a l-kharāja ʿalā l-arāḍī fa-innahum yamlikūna l-araḍīya wa-taṣiḥḥu minhum sāʾ iru t-taṣarrufāti min baiʿ in wa-hibatin wa-waṣīyatin wa-waqfin sawāʾan kāna l-mutaṣarrifu bāq...

Table of contents

  1. Cover
  2. Half Title
  3. Title
  4. Copyright
  5. Original Title
  6. Original Copyright
  7. Contents
  8. Dedication
  9. Preface
  10. Acknowledgements
  11. Notes on Transcription
  12. Preliminary Remarks
  13. 1. The Birth of the Kharāj Payer
  14. 2. The Contract of Tenancy (Ijāra): The 'Commodification' of the Productive Use of Land
  15. 3. The Share-cropping Contract (al-Muzāraʿa): Combining Dependent Labour with the Means of Production
  16. 4. The 'Death of the Proprietors'
  17. 5. The Ottoman Muftis' New Doctrine on Tax and Rent
  18. 6. Summary and Conclusion
  19. Bibliography
  20. Name Index
  21. Subject Index