Planning by Consent
eBook - ePub

Planning by Consent

The Origins and Nature of British Development Control

  1. 224 pages
  2. English
  3. ePUB (mobile friendly)
  4. Available on iOS & Android
eBook - ePub

Planning by Consent

The Origins and Nature of British Development Control

Book details
Book preview
Table of contents
Citations

About This Book

**Please note this is an unedited paperback reprint of the hardback, originally published in 2003**

The British system of universal development control celebrated its 50th anniversary in 1997. Remarkably, the system has survived more or less intact but the experience of the 1980s has left large questions unanswered about the relevance and effectiveness of the system. This book traces the history of the development control system in Britain from early modern times to the present day.

Frequently asked questions

Simply head over to the account section in settings and click on “Cancel Subscription” - it’s as simple as that. After you cancel, your membership will stay active for the remainder of the time you’ve paid for. Learn more here.
At the moment all of our mobile-responsive ePub books are available to download via the app. Most of our PDFs are also available to download and we're working on making the final remaining ones downloadable now. Learn more here.
Both plans give you full access to the library and all of Perlego’s features. The only differences are the price and subscription period: With the annual plan you’ll save around 30% compared to 12 months on the monthly plan.
We are an online textbook subscription service, where you can get access to an entire online library for less than the price of a single book per month. With over 1 million books across 1000+ topics, we’ve got you covered! Learn more here.
Look out for the read-aloud symbol on your next book to see if you can listen to it. The read-aloud tool reads text aloud for you, highlighting the text as it is being read. You can pause it, speed it up and slow it down. Learn more here.
Yes, you can access Planning by Consent by Philip Booth in PDF and/or ePUB format, as well as other popular books in Architecture & Urban Planning & Landscaping. We have over one million books available in our catalogue for you to explore.

Information

Publisher
Routledge
Year
2003
ISBN
9781135920586
Chapter One
The Glory of the British Planning System
The heart of British planning is the permitting system, strengthened by the government ownership of the development potential of land. This is one of the glories of the British system, but it also generates deep discontent—because the flexibility the planners prize in the system is viewed by the developers as too prone to arbitrary decision making and surprise rulings on proposed projects.
(Haar, 1984, p. 204)
To describe a process as banal as the filling out of an application form or the issuing a permit as a glory may seem far-fetched. For, at its most basic, development control is no more than that: the stuff of countless different administrative procedures designed to regulate aspects of our daily lives. But if the process is banal, its content need not necessarily be so: this routine bureaucratic procedure brings the public at large into contact with the nature of land-use change with a directness that almost nothing else achieves. It does so through the resolutely trivial, as in the proposal to build a back extension, as much as through the major project that may significantly alter a neighbourhood, a town or a region.
As a process, it does not get a good press. Planners are all too ready to permit some outrage to common decency in the environment; they take an inordinate time to make up their minds; their decisions are arbitrary, wilful or, worse, motivated by political dogma or financial gain. The process is seen as negative and reactive, bureaucratic and time wasting. It is overwhelmingly concerned with trivia. The planners themselves see it as a thankless task and one which they are happy to escape in favour of the seemingly more glamorous and intellectually challenging work of policy-making and evaluation. Neither the public nor the developers nor the planning profession itself appear to like development control very much even if no one has quite dared to suggest its outright abolition. We are emphatically not used to seeing it described as a ‘glory’.
Why then does Haar, an American lawyer, view British development control in such a favourable light? At the simplest level, the system of applying for a permit each time a land-use change is proposed is in no way unique to Britain. During the twentieth century all the developed countries of the world found comparable ways of controlling development, and all were founded on some general idea of a public good that would be served by such systems of control. In fact closer examination suggests that the superficial similarities—the making of applications, the issuing of permits—conceal significant differences of approach and underlying rationale. These differences are both of process and of content. Systems for controlling the urban environment do not necessarily share the same objectives. The process by which applications are dealt with and the way in which decisions are taken vary very markedly and reveal wide divergences in understanding about the nature of authority and accountability. Exploration of systems of control in these terms begins to reveal a British system which is clearly distinctive when compared with those in other parts of Europe or indeed in the rest of the world.
The essentials of the system are simply described. The Town and Country Planning Act passed in 1947, and not fundamentally altered since, sets out a definition of development that would cover all forms of land-use change. Anyone carrying out development, so defined, would need a valid planning permission before doing so. Finally, local authorities were given the task of determining planning applications. In carrying out their task, they were obliged to consider planning policy as set out in the development plans, which they were also required to prepare, as well as other circumstances that might bear upon the acceptability of the proposal. Not all development would require local authority consent. The legislation also allowed for consent to be given by order of the Minister responsible for planning. But the major interest in the system has always lain in the way in which local authorities have used their powers.
Put in these terms, the process hardly appears very remarkable. The oddness of the system by comparison with forms of control in other parts of the world only becomes fully apparent if we study the detailed wording of the Act itself. Two key sections of the current legislation have remained little changed from those of the 1947 Act. The first, Section 55, contains the definition of development. Development is defined not only as physical change, expressed in the phrase ‘building, engineering, mining or other operations in, on, over or under land’ but also ‘any material change of use of buildings or other land’. Several features of the wording are noteworthy: the apparent quaintness of the term ‘operations’; the reference to engineering and mining as well as to building; the inclusion of ‘material change of use’ without any further elaboration of what distinguishes a material change from any other. The all-embracing nature of the control is clear, as is the ability to conceive of an abstract quality—land use—as a concrete reality. No other planning system proposes a definition of this kind as a preliminary to control and no definition is as wide-ranging as that in British legislation.
Section 70, which sets out the criteria for determining applications for planning permission, is the second key part of the Act. Local authorities are required ‘to have regard to the development plan, insofar as it is material to the application, and to any other material considerations’. Though the originality of this wording has often been remarked upon, its effects are nevertheless worth rehearsing. First, it deliberately weakens the connection between the plan and the decision on a particular project. The Act specifically recognizes that a plan may not be pertinent to the decision to be taken. Equally, other factors may be as, or more, significant than the plan in determining the outcome of a planning application. No other planning system creates quite this kind of partial divorce between policy and control; most others derive their legitimacy from a pre-ordained set of regulations or some kind of zoning that spells out what is permissible to the developer and on what grounds the controlling authority must base its decision.
Secondly, the wording of Section 70 explicitly confers discretionary power on the local authority. It is for the authority to decide whether the plan is in fact material to the decision, and what other material considerations need to be taken into account. No other system offers quite this kind of discretionary freedom.
The wording of the Act was of course an expression of the preoccupations of politicians and administrators during the 1940s. Pressure had developed for a system that would be universal in its application. It had to include all forms of development and it had to apply regardless of the state of planning policy. The desire for universal control was summed up in the idea that legislation should nationalize the rights to future development of land. Although the legitimacy of State involvement in the control of development is shared by any system in which private activity is subject to public control, the particular formulation of the concept is idiosyncratically British. The British legal profession has always made great play with the right of the owner to ‘enjoy’ his or her property. We can note the way in which the 1947 Act divided the current ‘enjoyment’ of land (in other words, land in its current state) from its future development and so gave concrete existence to another essentially abstract concept.
Pressure had also built up for a system that would be flexible, hence the desire to loosen the absolute link between the plan and the development control decision. It was part of a pragmatic administrative tradition that rejected minutely prescribed limits in favour of a case-by-case approach that favoured precedent and procedural rules over substantive regulation. Finally, the wording confirms the role of local authorities in the control process. In general terms, British development control is not so very different from systems elsewhere. But the implication of Section 70 is that local authorities are not merely acting as agents of the State in controlling development, they are being given the freedom to determine their own destiny. The activity is not purely administrative, it becomes explicitly political. And, by further implication, the Act gives them freedom to negotiate the best solution to a given problem of development.
Underlying these general implications of the legislation are two longstanding and interlinked traditions. The first is that of common law with its heavy reliance on judge-made law. Other systems of law also use the judgements of the courts to inform the intentions of the legislation, but in common law judgements on individual cases have a central role (Waldron, 1990). Moreover statute law is framed in such a way that often allows judges to interpret general legislative intentions in the light of circumstance. Case law has remained highly significant for the understanding of the way in which the law may be used. The apparently unfettered freedoms contained in sections of the Town and Country Planning Act have in practice been subject to judicial scrutiny and the limits to discretionary behaviour have been set. But the way in which judges have behaved, in referring to legal precedent, in balancing competing interests and in applying generalized tests to particular cases, has come to inform administrative practice, too.
The other tradition which underlies the discretionary powers of the Act is that of procedural fairness. The power to decide is legitimated, not by reference to regulation carrying the force of law, but by the way in which the decision is taken. It implies a trust in the behaviour of those appointed or elected to take decisions. It also requires a judicial scrutiny of the way in which decisions are taken. Significant among the legal tests that judges will apply to administrative behaviour is whether the decision-maker acted ultra vires—beyond the powers accorded by law. Yet within those powers, those who take decisions must also show that they did so fairly and reasonably.
Other Systems of Control
In all of this the contrast with planning systems in most other parts of Europe is striking. The contrast is most marked when Britain is compared with those countries that form part of the Napoleonic inheritance. In France, for example, the very different terms in which planning is discussed gives a clue to the divergence of Britain and its European neighbours. In Britain, much of the discussion about planning in general and development control in particular has centred on the need for flexibility, and on how that flexibility might be achieved. In France on the other hand, the discourse has focused on the terms sĂ©curitĂ© and certitude—(legal) security and certainty—as tests of good planning. Where in Britain we have been content with a pragmatic vagueness in our planning legislation, the French look for clarity and precision.
The reasons for this emphasis on precision and definition are bound up with the way in which the legal system has been used to define rights and duties. Property rights in France could not in theory or in practice be divided in the way that they were in Britain after the 1947 Act. Future use and development of land were as much part of the right to property protected by the constitution as was current enjoyment. This did not mean the State had no right to interfere in property rights, however. French lawyers could conceptualize the power of the State in terms of the Roman law principle of imperium, the overarching control by the State of its citizens, within which dominium, the right to private property, had to be couched (Gaudemet, 1995). The effect of conceptualizing property in this way was to place great emphasis on the need to identify precisely what the rights guaranteed by the constitution actually amounted to. Codified law could spell out in immense detail what the rights and duties of citizens and government alike would be. The citizen would know what he or she was expected to do, and what might be expected of the administration. In theory, nothing would be left to chance.
This insistence on certainty and on rights and obligations finds a clear expression in the French planning system. Like most French administrative law, the legislation for town planning is codified but the code, quite apart from setting out processes and procedures, also covers matters of what in Britain would be called policy and not law. Indeed, the distinction between law and policy which is highly significant in Britain is largely absent in France. The detailed land-use plans created under the town planning code are not thought of as a general statement of land-use policy in the way that their British counterparts would be. Plans d’occupation des sols (local land-use plans)1 create zones for every part of the territory they cover, and for every zone there are precise instructions expressed as regulations carrying the force of law. These regulations are written under 15 headings prescribed by the code itself. In this way, the plan becomes a substitute for the code. It identifies precisely how property owners may exercise their rights to dominium and what the grounds for decision-making by public authorities will be. As with codified law in general, in theory nothing is left to chance and rights and obligations are clearly specified (see Booth,1996).
France, no less than Britain, has a system of permits, the permis de construire, authorizing specific projects. But although the making and determination of applications bears a superficial resemblance to British practice, the legitimacy of the process has very different foundations. The working of the code gives some indication of this difference. Where the part of the British Town and Country Planning Act dealing with development control begins with the all-embracing definition of development, in the French code the starting point is an obligation:
Whosoever desires to undertake or establish a construction, whether for residential purposes or not and whether or not on foundations, must first obtain a permission to build
(Article L. 421–1)
Quite apart from the duty that is imposed by this article of the code, we may note that the main thrust of the requirement is in relation to physical development not, as in the British case, to land use.
Where a plan d’occupation des sols is in force, a decision must be taken by reference to the plan, and in theory at least, the person making an application will have a very good idea about the acceptability of proposal before the permission is granted. Indeed, a proposal which conforms in every detail to the plan and its regulations must be approved. In this light, the way in which the application is dealt with is by a process distinctly different from that in Britain. The primary concern is to know whether the project is legal in that it conforms to the regulations in force, not whether it is appropriate for the place and the circumstance. Unlike the partial divorce of plan and development control decision in Britain, the relationship in the French case is absolute and binding. As if to emphasize the point, until 1983 decisions were taken by the local mayor acting not in a political capacity as an elected representative but as an agent of the State. Although that is no longer true for much of the country, the mayor’s duty is everywhere to uphold the law as much as to further the interests of his or her commune.
Just as with the insistence on flexibility in the British system, the creation of a system that places a premium on certainty has created as many problems as it has solved. The practice of development control in France displays a great deal of discretionary behaviour and political decision-making. Fixed regulations turn out to be considerably less fixed that they at first appear. But there is a significant difference between the discretion offered by British legislation and the discretionary behaviour of French officials. In Britain, in general, discretionary freedom is formally conferred on local authorities by the wording of the Act. In France, the possibilities for exercising discretion are often not explicit. Where there is explicit choice offered by the law, it is confined to the way in which a particular regulation in the code or in the plan is applied. Cumulatively, this may amount to very considerable discretionary leverage on the development proposal to be determined. That in turn has given rise to renewed call for clarity and certainty within the system.
So the legitimacy of the French system of development control depends upon a tradition of law quite unlike that of the common law system of Britain. But though the characteristics of British development control are in part due to the nature of common law, it does not follow that other countries whose legal systems depend on common law have adopted the same approach to planning as Britain. In the United States, for example, the existence of a written constitution and the emphasis placed on the individual’s right to own property led some to question whether the State had any right to intervene in the development process at all. For Americans, the key concept is that of the ‘taking’ (that is an unlawful denial of the property owner’s rights to his or her land) and the question that judges are at pains to determine is whether any form of State action amounts to an unwarranted interference with the rights and liberties of the individual guaranteed by the constitution.
That question was successfully resolved for zoning ordinances in the 1920s by the Ambler Realty v. The Village of Euclid case following which zoning became an acceptable part of American way of life. The justification of the Euclid case was that zoning could be equated with other forms of ‘police’ powers which the State legitimately exercised to ensure the rights of everyone. At the time, Euclid was seen as a famous victory for planning, but as Haar (1989) has pointed out, the reason that zoning so quickly established itself in the United States was because developers saw a considerable advantage in a system that introduced a degree of order into an otherwise chaotic land market. And of course for residents too zoning had its distinct attractions. Put grandly, it was the means by which their constitutional rights as owners and occupiers could be guaranteed. In more cynical terms, zoning would become the means by which the physical and social character, and particularly the latter, could be protected from unwarranted invasion.
In theory, zoning ordinances were the detailed expression of policy set out in land-use plans. In practice, zoning ordinances appear to have developed a life of their own existing as often as not in isolation as the only planning document that applies in many urban areas. Even more than French plans d’occupation des sols, zoning ordinances all too often appear to freeze a status quo, and offer nothing in terms of a prospective vision. Zoning has also fuelled American litigiousness. The narrow constraints of zoning ordinances, far from deterring unwanted development, seem merely to have encouraged the legal ingenuity of developers. Overcoming these constraints has led to battles to be fought out in court, the ‘zoning game’ eloquently evoked by Babcock (1966) and Babcock and Siemon (1990). In this context, the flexibility of the British development control system begins to look enviably attractive, not least because it only rarely involves the courts.
The rigidities of American zoning have elicited ingenuity in the planning profession, too. Cullingworth (1993) and Wakeford (1990) have noted the various devices that some American zoning ordinances have used to create flexibility and choice and to allow for negotiated development. The critical reaction to these devices is not all negative. Wakeford wondered whether the ‘special interest’ zoning used in San Francisco, which allowed the city authorities to protect areas of a particular mixed-use character from market forces, might not be useful in Britain. Far more doubtful has been the technique of ‘incentive zoning’, first introduced in the New York zoning ordinance of 1961. The zoning allowed, but did not require, the provision of a plaza in exchange for an increase in floor area ratio, as a means of encouraging developers to provide public open space. The policy worked to the extent that downtown New York has acquired a large number of such plazas and the device has been used to secure other ends in cities across the United States. Yet as Cullingworth (1993) points out, the utility of providing downtown Manhattan with so many plazas is far from clear and the cost of doing so has been great. Above all, the benefit is not tied to a coherent planning policy. In the search for flexibility, zoning had moved away from a simple declaration of development rights and constraints.
The conclusions that we can draw from such comparisons are not that one system of development control is necessarily better than any other. More to the point is the fact that all systems of planning face inherent problems: how to contain future uncertainty; how to allow for appropriate response to the unforeseen circumstance; how to ensure that discretionary behaviour is exercised responsibly. The response to such problems is of course the product of the political, administrative and legal culture of particular countries. The unwanted effects of these diverse responses are equally diverse. Emphasize certainty as the key attribute of a system of control and you find that the subterfuges used to surmount constraints threatens the very legitimacy of the system. Elevate flexibility as the touchstone of the effective planning system and you may find yourself enmeshed in impenetrable ambiguities which do not serve anyone very well (for a further discussion of these id...

Table of contents

  1. Cover
  2. Half Title
  3. Title Page
  4. Copyright
  5. Contents
  6. Preface
  7. Acknowledgements
  8. Chapter 1. The Glory of the British Planning System
  9. Chapter 2. Property, Contract and Regulation: Urban Control before Planning
  10. Chapter 3. The Search for Flexibility
  11. Chapter 4. Towards Universal Control
  12. Chapter 5. Control by Consents: The 1947 Act and After
  13. Chapter 6. Development Control in a Market Economy
  14. Chapter 7. Towards the New Millennium
  15. Chapter 8. Future Glory?
  16. Bibliography
  17. Index