The Route to European Hegemony
eBook - ePub

The Route to European Hegemony

India's Intra-Asian Trade in the Early Modern Period (Sixteenth to Eighteenth Centuries)

  1. 316 pages
  2. English
  3. ePUB (mobile friendly)
  4. Available on iOS & Android
eBook - ePub

The Route to European Hegemony

India's Intra-Asian Trade in the Early Modern Period (Sixteenth to Eighteenth Centuries)

Book details
Book preview
Table of contents
Citations

About This Book

The advent of the Europeans was crucial in transforming the contours of Maritime Asia. The commercial situation in the Indian Ocean was impacted in many ways over the longue duree from the sixteenth to the eighteenth centuries. To offset the adverse balance of trade and to maximize profits, the Europeans imposed their own coercive and monopolistic systems along the existing trade routes. Systematic exploitation of economic opportunities in Asia by Europeans began with the coming of the Portuguese, followed by other European maritime powers. It culminated with Britannia ruling the Asian waters with warships and a strong merchant marine.
A study of the operational and ideological motivations that propelled the European powers' activities in the Indian Ocean can help to construct a coherent interpretation of the foundations of empire that were being laid, at first insidiously and later, aggressively.

This book analyses the mechanism and implications of Europe's sustained engagement in Intra-Asian trade which is as an essential context to the establishment of colonial empires.

Please note: Taylor & Francis does not sell or distribute the Hardback in India, Pakistan, Nepal, Bhutan, Bangladesh and Sri Lanka.

Frequently asked questions

Simply head over to the account section in settings and click on “Cancel Subscription” - it’s as simple as that. After you cancel, your membership will stay active for the remainder of the time you’ve paid for. Learn more here.
At the moment all of our mobile-responsive ePub books are available to download via the app. Most of our PDFs are also available to download and we're working on making the final remaining ones downloadable now. Learn more here.
Both plans give you full access to the library and all of Perlego’s features. The only differences are the price and subscription period: With the annual plan you’ll save around 30% compared to 12 months on the monthly plan.
We are an online textbook subscription service, where you can get access to an entire online library for less than the price of a single book per month. With over 1 million books across 1000+ topics, we’ve got you covered! Learn more here.
Look out for the read-aloud symbol on your next book to see if you can listen to it. The read-aloud tool reads text aloud for you, highlighting the text as it is being read. You can pause it, speed it up and slow it down. Learn more here.
Yes, you can access The Route to European Hegemony by Ruby Maloni in PDF and/or ePUB format, as well as other popular books in History & Indian & South Asian History. We have over one million books available in our catalogue for you to explore.

Information

Publisher
Routledge
Year
2021
ISBN
9781000373233
Edition
1

CHAPTER 1
Politico-Economic Ramifications of Europe’s Intra-Asian Trade

The traditional view of the Indian Ocean and Asian trade during the sixteenth to the eighteenth centuries has been altered by recent studies. Fresh problems have been posited and new answers have been offered. What once appeared to be a series of isolated trading enclaves on the fringes of the vast land oriented continent of Asia is now recognized as a wide and intricate commercial network, pivoting mostly on the Indian subcontinent and sharing a large portion of the world’s total trade. The economic history of the early modern period in Asia is much more than the operations and impact of a neat succession of Portuguese, Dutch, English and French commercial enterprises. Other European commercial ventures such as the Danish East India Company and the Ostend Company lost no time in entering the fray, with the objective of accruing large profits. Indigenous economies existed, with their own robust mercantile communities and long established practices, which continued to be integral to the Indian Ocean littoral. This phase can be understood as a time that witnessed the formation of a formal relationship between countries in the two continents, Europe and Asia. This was the first Age of Globalization, a world of exchange, resulting from what Fernand Braudel terms the ‘wheels of commerce’.1
In Europe, a close inter-relationship existed between economic practice and political ideology in the early world systems that evolved. Commercial relations were such that protection and expansion were reflections of their logic. The European powers’ deeply ingrained mercantilist quest for a trading monopoly reached the Indian Ocean, with commercial ascendancy followed by political dominance. An economic relationship was the most important vehicle of contact between Europe and Asia. Played out on the stage of the Indian Ocean, this relationship would lead to many Asian regions becoming the victims of colonialism and imperialism. Related to Intra-Asian trade was the imposition of European hegemony in Asia.
In 1498 Vasco da Gama sailed from Portugal to India around the Cape of Good Hope and opened a new sea route to the East. The early phase of colonialism dawned in Asia when the Portuguese set up fortified settlements, and levied tribute on indigenous shipping. Mercantilism thus had firm roots in national defence and aggression, policies of the Portuguese in the sixteenth century being followed by other European maritime powers in the Indian Ocean in the seventeenth century. European trade in Asia was unequivocally monopolistic in nature, in contrast to the multiple networks of indigenous commerce that were prevalent in the Indian Ocean economy during the same time.
European commercial practices in the Indian Ocean network can be traced to the deeply ingrained ideology of mercantilism, which existed roughly between 1498 and 1776.2 The crucible of mercantilism was Europe. This term denotes the ‘state making’ activities that the European nations pursued, which were political and economic in nature. An important aspect of the mercantilist period was the fusion of the merchants and the state, a process which gave great power to the government and led to the creation of empire. The state framed policies that were conducive to the merchants, and the merchants in turn supplied financial resources for the state, mainly to improve their defences. Trade was carried out with the national interest in mind and thus required a licence from the government.3 Mercantilism in England was characterized by the state and the English East India Company.4 Andre Gunder Frank confirms that mercantile expansion was related to the consolidation of the national state and its power.5
In Europe, defensive mercantilism or economic nationalism became expansive and thus imperialistic.6 Mercantilism had become the major school of economic thought in many parts of Europe throughout the late Renaissance and the early modern period.7 Evidence of mercantilist practices appeared in early modern Venice, Genoa and Pisa regarding control of the Mediterranean trade in bullion. Mercantilism denoted a national economic policy aimed at accumulating monetary reserves by means of a positive balance of trade. It promoted government regulation of a nation’s economy for the purpose of augmenting state power at the expense of rival state powers. Historically, such policies frequently led to war and also motivated colonial expansion. The Guyanese historian, Walter Rodney, describes mercantilism as the period of the worldwide development of European commerce, which began in the fifteenth century with the voyages of Portuguese and Spanish explorers to Africa, Asia, and the New World system.8 John Kenneth Galbraith has held that merchant capitalism of mercantilism was anything but a system. According to him, it prevailed for about 300 years from the middle of the fifteenth century to the middle of the eighteenth century. He identifies the end of mercantilism as the period when the Industrial Revolution began and to the publishing of Adam Smith’s economic theory in 1776.9
Mercantilism, as the dominant economic ideology of all of Europe in the early modern period, was embraced by most states to a certain degree. Mercantilism was rooted in England10 and France, and it was in these states that mercantilist policies were most often enacted. England began the first large scale and integrative approach to mercantilism during the Elizabethan era (1558-1603). An early statement on the national balance of trade appeared in A Discourse of the Common Weal of this Realm of England, published in 1549, ‘We must always take heed that we buy no more from strangers than we sell them, for so should we impoverish ourselves and enrich them.’11 Queen Elizabeth I promoted the Trade and Navigation Acts in Parliament and issued orders to her navy for the protection and promotion of English shipping. The EIC was established by a royal charter on the last day of 1600, with a monopoly of trade with the East, and permission to export annually treasure—gold, silver and coin—up to the value of £ 30,000.12 This created a sense of financial anxiety in England, since export of gold and silver was held to be against a country’s interest under the prevailing doctrine of mercantilism. An answer to the critics was provided by Thomas Mun, a director of the EIC. Mun’s systematic explanation of the balance of trade, England’s Treasure by Forraign Trade, or the Ballance of our Forraign Trade is The Rule of Our Treasure (Plate 1), written in the 1620s and published in 1664, became the seventeenth century manifesto of mercantilism and economic development.13 Mun’s ideas on mercantile policies, which influenced the dominant merchants in England, included the aim to reduce imports by refraining from excessive consumption of foreign wares, to trade in English ships for higher profits, to ensure import of corn, indigo, spices, raw silk and raw cotton so that they could be exported as required, and to reduce restrictions on trade and allowances.14 While arguing for free trade, Mun still supported the monopoly of the EIC over the Eastern trade as the only path to profit. This economic theory was further promoted and put into practice by Josiah Child, merchant-pamphleteer and governor of the EIC. He advocated the EIC’s claims to political power, as well as to its right of restricting competition to its trade. In order to avoid England’s export of treasure, his proposal was to impose a heavy indemnity on the Mughal empire and carve out an ‘English dominion in India’. This led to a disastrous ‘war’ with the Mughals in 1686-90. Child’s principal work in defence of the EIC, A New Discourse of Trade, published in 1668, held the interest of economists for a long time.15 Henry Martyn’s Considerations Upon the East India Trade, published anonymously in 1701, claimed that the East India trade could actually become an instrument of capital accumulation, which in its turn would stimulate industrial development and higher productivity. It represented the ideas of political economy that took shape in Britain in the eighteenth century.16 The importance of colonial plunder for the development of capitalism in Britain was underlined by Karl Marx in Capital, published in 1867.17
French mercantilism was articulated by theorists like Jean Boden, and most prominently by finance ministers, Jean-Baptiste Colbert and Jacques Necker.18 Dutch understanding of their commercial power in the seventeenth century has been understood by some historians to be somewhat unique.19 There was some truth to the assertion of their commercial rivals that Dutch policy was formulated according to the prudential criteria of an enlarged corporation rather than the ideology of a state.20 Mercantilism signified the preservation of conditions by which the Dutch Republic’s trade could flourish without hindrance and the perpetuation of economic supremacy. Immanuel Wallerstein has described this domination as also a form of global ‘hegemony’.21
In Europe, academic belief in aggressive mercantilism began to fade in the late eighteenth century, especially in Britain, in light of the arguments of Adam Smith and classical economists like David Hume, David Ricardo, Dudley North and John Locke. The main rebuttal of the argument of the mercantilists came from Adam Smith, who castigated the EIC as the repository of monopoly power and economic inefficiency. The publication of his major work, An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations,22 had a wide impact, and laissez-faire economics was embraced by the British empire which then used its power as the financial centre of the world to promote free trade across the globe for its own benefit. By the mid nineteenth century, the British empire moved away from mercantilism and trade restrictions, but only in ways suiting its commercial convenience.
Irfan Habib points out that while economists like Adam Smith adopted a critical attitude towards the policy of colonial acquisition, their theoretical premises could be extended to justify the policy of both tribute and colonial acquisitions.23 Raw materials and wage-goods would obviously lower costs of production. Such an advantage to the ruling country was allowed for by David Ricardo in the chapter on ‘Colonial Trade’ in On the Principles of Political Economy and Taxation, published in 1817.24 Colonial possessions would enlarge the market for the ruling country’s products, for it could then manipulate tariffs in the acquired territory to its own advantage. Jeremy Bentham and the Utilitarians professed free trade principles, and yet expounded a policy of aggressive colonialism. James Mill, the leading Utilitarian spokesman related to India, told a Parliamentary committee in 1832 that the best course was ‘to make war’ on the Indian princely states and annex them. Richard Cobden, leader of the Radicals, though opposing war, kept in mind the interests of the Manchester (Lancashire) cotton mill owners. In 1857, Cobden stated, ‘If you talk to our Lanc...

Table of contents

  1. Cover
  2. Half Title
  3. Title Page
  4. Copyright Page
  5. Dedication Page
  6. Contents
  7. Illustrations and Maps
  8. Preface
  9. 1. Politico-Economic Ramifications of Europe’s Intra-Asian Trade
  10. 2. Indian Maritime Centres: Foreland and Hinterland
  11. 3. Indian Merchants and Institutional Structures: Resilience and Resistance
  12. 4. European Merchants at Indian Ports: Contest for Profit Maximization
  13. 5. The English East India Company: Commercial Power and Dominance
  14. Bibliography
  15. Index