Government and Merchant Finance in Anglo-Gascon Trade, 1300–1500
eBook - ePub

Government and Merchant Finance in Anglo-Gascon Trade, 1300–1500

  1. English
  2. ePUB (mobile friendly)
  3. Available on iOS & Android
eBook - ePub

Government and Merchant Finance in Anglo-Gascon Trade, 1300–1500

Book details
Book preview
Table of contents
Citations

About This Book

The Late Middle Ages (c.1300–c.1500) saw the development of many of the key economic institutions of the modern unitary nation-state in Europe. After the 'commercial revolution' of the thirteenth century, taxes on trade became increasingly significant contributors to government finances, and as such there were ever greater efforts to control the flow of goods and money.

This book presents a case study of the commercial and financial links between the kingdom of England and the duchy of Aquitaine across the late-medieval period, with a special emphasis on the role of the English Plantagenet government that had ruled both in a political union since 1154. It establishes a strong connection between fluctuations in commodity markets, large monetary flows and unstable financial markets, most notably in trade credit and equity partnerships.

It shows how the economic relationship deteriorated under the many exogenous shocks of the period, the wars, plagues and famines, as well as politically motivated regulatory intervention. Despite frequent efforts to innovate in response, both merchants and governments experienced a series of protracted financial crises that presaged the break-up of the union of kingdom and duchy in 1453, with the latter's conquest by the French crown. Of particular interest to scholars of the late-medieval European economy, this book will also appeal to those researching wider economic or financial history.

Frequently asked questions

Simply head over to the account section in settings and click on “Cancel Subscription” - it’s as simple as that. After you cancel, your membership will stay active for the remainder of the time you’ve paid for. Learn more here.
At the moment all of our mobile-responsive ePub books are available to download via the app. Most of our PDFs are also available to download and we're working on making the final remaining ones downloadable now. Learn more here.
Both plans give you full access to the library and all of Perlego’s features. The only differences are the price and subscription period: With the annual plan you’ll save around 30% compared to 12 months on the monthly plan.
We are an online textbook subscription service, where you can get access to an entire online library for less than the price of a single book per month. With over 1 million books across 1000+ topics, we’ve got you covered! Learn more here.
Look out for the read-aloud symbol on your next book to see if you can listen to it. The read-aloud tool reads text aloud for you, highlighting the text as it is being read. You can pause it, speed it up and slow it down. Learn more here.
Yes, you can access Government and Merchant Finance in Anglo-Gascon Trade, 1300–1500 by Robert Blackmore in PDF and/or ePUB format, as well as other popular books in Economics & Economic History. We have over one million books available in our catalogue for you to explore.

Information

Year
2020
ISBN
9783030345365
© The Author(s) 2020
R. BlackmoreGovernment and Merchant Finance in Anglo-Gascon Trade, 1300–1500Palgrave Studies in the History of Financehttps://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-34536-5_1
Begin Abstract

1. Introduction

Robert Blackmore1
(1)
Oxford, UK
Robert Blackmore
End Abstract

1.1 Origins

The history of Europe is marked by cycles of political and economic integration followed by disintegration. Among these, few were as lasting or fruitful, whilst also as troubled, as that which unified the kingdom of England with a large swathe of the continent in the Middle Ages. Though this began with the Norman Conquest in 1066, it reached new heights when the duchy of Aquitaine was appended to the English crown after the accession of Henry of Anjou or Plantagenet (d.1189) as King Henry II of England on 25 October 1154. Two years earlier, he had married Eleanor of Aquitaine, the former wife of King Louis VII of France (r.1137–80), and the heiress to Guillém X, duke of Aquitaine (1099–1137).1 The duchy would remain in the hands of the Plantagenet dynasty (1154–1485) for nearly three centuries—almost without interruption—until 1453, when it fell under the direct rule of the French crown at the end of the Hundred Years’ War (1337–1453).
Political union prefigured close commercial and financial ties between England and Aquitaine. A c.1465 memorandum penned by Régnault Girard, a French royal official, later explained this to his king, Louis XI (r.1461–83). Girard told of the hundreds of ships that had conducted a great trade route down the Atlantic seaboard of Europe. He listed the ‘great merchandise’ that came south: ‘fine English wool made into abundant cloth’, tin, lead, coal, and more. For this, wine returned north, as well as other products from across southern France: from the lands of the lords of Albret, the counts of Armagnac and Foix, and the viscounts of Béarn, as well as farther afield from the kingdoms of Castile, Navarre, and Aragon. Girard himself observed that with commerce would flow money, gold, and silver, and this would infuse and stimulate the economy.2 It was not until a convergence of political and military events in the thirteenth century that this strong link properly developed. The reign of Henry II’s son John (r.1199–1216) brought a series of disastrous defeats at the hands of Philip II Augustus of France (r.1180–1223), during which most of the Plantagenet lands in France, apart from southern and western Aquitaine, were lost.3 Finally, in August 1224, Philip’s son Louis VIII (r.1223–6) captured what remained of Poitou and La Rochelle from Henry III (r.1216–72).4 The residue was Gascony, stretching roughly from the Pyrenees mountains to the Garonne river. The region’s ports, particularly the cities of Bordeaux and Bayonne, thereafter rose to prominence through strategic necessity. Fortuitously enough, this development coincided with a period of Europe-wide demographic and economic expansion, coupled with growth in the scale and sophistication of trade, described since Raymond de Roover as a ‘commercial revolution’.5 Anglo-Gascon trade grew apace from this time, stimulated by a burgeoning English demand for wine. In order to meet this demand, there was a dramatic expansion of vineyard land that accompanied the establishment of bastides, new settled towns.6 Particularly significant was the growth of production in the Haut-Pays (the ‘high country’), the lands to the east of the diocese of Bordeaux along the upper Garonne, Lot, Tarn, and, to an extent, the Dordogne rivers. This became, in the words of Michael Postan, ‘the largest region of specialised viticulture ever known in European history’.7 Such profound specialisation created a strong demand for goods that were not produced domestically in sufficient quantities, and in meeting those needs, England gained reliable access to wider European markets unhindered by the political constraints often found trading through France and the Low Countries. With this commercial expansion, the financial value of the union to the English crown rose exponentially.

1.2 The Study of Anglo-Gascon Union

This book is a study of Anglo-Gascon trade and finance in the Late Middle Ages, with a focus on their relationship with the Plantagenet government of England and Aquitaine. The period covered (around 1300 to 1500) can be credited with the development of many of the key economic institutions of the modern unitary nation-state in Europe, the main catalyst of which was the fiscal needs of governments. Following the ‘commercial revolution’ in the thirteenth century, taxes on trade made an increasingly important contribution to their finances. Richard Unger has argued—in his comprehensive review—that though rulers rarely made efforts to encourage long-distance commerce directly, they would exploit it ‘to increase their fiscal scope’ and gain ‘a regular, continuing and growing stream of money’.8 Unger saw governments—large and small—becoming increasingly reliant on such exactions over the fourteenth and fifteenth centuries, and that this process influenced the character of European polities as late as the seventeenth and eighteenth centuries.9 Yet, during the 200 years after 1300, rulers and merchants alike had to address growing threats to their prosperity as they left the last great period of economic growth of the High Middle Ages, and they entered, what is broadly defined as the late medieval, an era of—at best—great insecurity—at worst—outright decline. This brought increasingly regulated commodity and capital markets, and more centralised systems of taxation and public borrowing. Financial innovations of the former age, be they companies or credit instruments, became increasingly refined and applied more widely to deal with the great challenges of the latter.10
An examination of the union of England and Aquitaine offers a valuable perspective on such changes. Trade between two polities with one ruler generated subtly different financial challenges and political outcomes as their economies were buffeted by the effects of repeated exogenous shocks. Some of these were obviously more or less universal: Europe’s population began to fall with the great famines of 1315–22. The Black Death followed in 1348–50. During the first wave of plague (Yersinia pestis), somewhere between one-third and one-half of the continent’s inhabitants died; and further deadly outbreaks recurred thereafter. The population of England went from close to five million down to a little over two million by the end of the fourteenth century.11 One can estimate that the nucleus of Plantagenet Aquitaine contained 650,000 taxpayers in 1315–6, but not much more than 150,000 in 1414.12 Political strife and conflicts were increasingly frequent. The 1259 Treaty of Paris—agreed by Henry III and Louis IX (r.1226–70)—had confirmed the vassalage of the English king to the French for the tenure of Aquitaine, but the late thirteenth and early fourteenth centuries saw repeated quarrelling between the two crowns over the extent of the sovereignty of each.13 This book begins at the time of the 1294–1303 Anglo-French War between Edward I (r.1272–1307) and the Capetian King Philip IV, also known as Philip the Fair (r.1285–1314). The 1324 War of Saint-Sardos between Charles IV (r.1322–8) and Edward II (r.1307–27) lasted just six weeks and was a military disaster for the English. It led to the loss of much of the east of the duchy and contributed to Edward’s removal from power in 1326.14 Friction continued between Edward III (r.1327–77) and Philip VI of Valois (r.1328–50) until finally, in 1337, Philip ordered the confiscation of all remaining Plantagenet lands held of the French crown, beginning the Hundred Years’ War.15 English fortunes waxed in the 1340s and 1350s under Edward and his son Edward of Woodstock, the Black Prince (1330–76), then waned in the 1370s and through the reign of Richard II (r.1377–9). The Lancastrian usurpation by Henry IV (r.1399–1413) brought a military resurgence under the leadership of Henry V (r.1413–22), and then another decline under his son Henry VI (r.1422–70, 1471). The final conquest of Aquitaine by the French King Charles VII (r.1422–61) in 1453 brought an ultimate threat to commercial and financial links between England and Aquitaine by suddenly removing their political basis.
As we approach the relevant historiography, some clarification of the correct nomenclature is necessary. The kingdom of England, often referred to here as ‘the kingdom’, more or less covered its mod...

Table of contents

  1. Cover
  2. Front Matter
  3. 1. Introduction
  4. 2. The Politics of Markets
  5. 3. Commodities and Prices
  6. 4. Money and Trade
  7. 5. Mercantile Finance
  8. 6. Public Finance
  9. 7. Conclusion
  10. Back Matter