Managing Leader Selection in European Political Parties
eBook - ePub

Managing Leader Selection in European Political Parties

  1. English
  2. ePUB (mobile friendly)
  3. Available on iOS & Android
eBook - ePub

Managing Leader Selection in European Political Parties

Book details
Book preview
Table of contents
Citations

About This Book

This book explores the varying ways in which political parties in Europe make arguably their most important decisions: the selection of their leaders. The choice shapes the representation of a party externally. It also influences the management of internal conflict, because there will always be some disagreement about the party's direction. The rules of selection will naturally affect the outcome. Yet there is more to it than rules. Sometimes the process is open and fiercely contested. Sometimes the field of potential leaders is filtered even before the decision reaches the selectorate – the organ that, according to party statutes, formally makes the appointment. The selectorate might have only a single candidate to ratify, a so-called 'coronation'. The book presents a framework for analysing both the formal and informal sides of leader selection, and hones the framework through its application in a series of case studies from nine European countries.

Frequently asked questions

Simply head over to the account section in settings and click on “Cancel Subscription” - it’s as simple as that. After you cancel, your membership will stay active for the remainder of the time you’ve paid for. Learn more here.
At the moment all of our mobile-responsive ePub books are available to download via the app. Most of our PDFs are also available to download and we're working on making the final remaining ones downloadable now. Learn more here.
Both plans give you full access to the library and all of Perlego’s features. The only differences are the price and subscription period: With the annual plan you’ll save around 30% compared to 12 months on the monthly plan.
We are an online textbook subscription service, where you can get access to an entire online library for less than the price of a single book per month. With over 1 million books across 1000+ topics, we’ve got you covered! Learn more here.
Look out for the read-aloud symbol on your next book to see if you can listen to it. The read-aloud tool reads text aloud for you, highlighting the text as it is being read. You can pause it, speed it up and slow it down. Learn more here.
Yes, you can access Managing Leader Selection in European Political Parties by Nicholas Aylott, Niklas Bolin, Nicholas Aylott,Niklas Bolin, Nicholas Aylott, Niklas Bolin in PDF and/or ePUB format, as well as other popular books in Politics & International Relations & Public Policy. We have over one million books available in our catalogue for you to explore.
© The Author(s) 2021
N. Aylott, N. Bolin (eds.)Managing Leader Selection in European Political PartiesPalgrave Studies in Political Leadershiphttps://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-55000-4_1
Begin Abstract

1. Conflicts and Coronations: Analysing Leader Selection in European Political Parties

Nicholas Aylott1 and Niklas Bolin2
(1)
School of Social Sciences, Södertörn University, Huddinge, Sweden
(2)
Department of Humanities and Social Sciences, Mid Sweden University, Sundsvall, Sweden
Nicholas Aylott (Corresponding author)
Niklas Bolin
End Abstract

Introduction

Political parties shape politics, and the most important person in a party is usually the leader. Party leaders make the political weather.
Take a recent example from Britain. In 2015 the Labour Party, somewhat unexpectedly, lost a national election. Its leader resigned and a new one was needed. “Jeremy Corbyn is not going to win the Labour leadership election”, insisted one of the country’s shrewdest political commentators (Rentoul 2015). But Corbyn did win, and by a comfortable margin. Labour thus took a big stride to the left. Among much else, a long-forgotten strain of left-wing Euroscepticism was reintroduced into the top of the party. It probably contributed to the sensational result in 2016 of Britain’s referendum on European Union membership; another Labour parliamentarian declared that Corbyn’s lukewarm engagement in the pro-membership campaign had fatally weakened it (Wilson 2016). The referendum outcome led, in turn, to a colossally tense period in the country’s politics. The economy, the party system, the constitution, even the territorial composition of the state were questioned amid Brexit-related uncertainty.
How did it happen? How did Corbyn, previously seen as an eccentric, marginal figure within his party, possibly win its leadership? A short answer, which is all we need for now, is that a new selection method, which Labour tried for the first time, contributed greatly—albeit in conjunction with several other factors—to Corbyn’s astounding victory. It is fair to say that an apparently modest institutional reform turned out to have profound consequences.
So while there is a long-running debate in political science about the normative value of “intra-party democracy” (Cross and Katz 2014; Teorell 1999), there are also strong substantive reasons for studying leader selection. It involves perhaps the most important decision that a party takes, and only rarely does the party lack any degree of realistic choice. The individuals who aspire to the job are, needless to say, almost always political figures, who have each established a reputation in regard to ideology and strategy—a brand, to use more economic language. Thus, in selecting its leader, the party also chooses the direction in which, at that moment, it prefers to travel—and that choice can change the political landscape. Corbyn’s success is one good example. Another can be taken from Estonia. As we will see in the following chapter in this volume, the decision in 2016 of the Centre Party to change its leader transformed—within days—the composition of the government and the shape of the entire party system.
Most European countries are parliamentary democracies, which means that power is centred in their national parliaments. Decision-making in a collective body like a parliament requires parties in order for things to get done (Thies 2000). The logic of election to these bodies, in which aspiring politicians try to attract electoral support through coordinating their promises, also militates strongly towards politics based on parties (StrĂžm 2003: 67–70). “European democracies”, therefore, “are not only parliamentary democracies but also party democracies” (MĂŒller 2000: 309). Yet, despite the prevalence of parliamentarism, we know that parties’ methods of choosing their leaders differ strikingly. For a start, the “selectorate”—the section or organ within a party that has the ultimate right to select the leader—might be the party’s members of parliament (MPs), its congress, the entire party membership, or some combination of these. It could even comprise any self-professed sympathiser who is prepared to pay a small fee—such as in the British Labour Party in 2015.1
We can assume that there is some regularity in the preference orders held by different parts of a party—members, activists, leaders, politicians (May 1973; Sjöblom 1968). If so, then the relative weight of those different parts in how the party selects its leader will affect the party’s behaviour. It could influence, for instance, whether the party tends to prioritise ideological purity, policy influence, government office or maximising its vote (StrĂžm and MĂŒller 1999). In regard to the ways in which parties and party systems mediate the relationship between democratic elections and public policy, we see party leader selection as a crucial node. Our goal in this book is to establish a procedure for comparing leader selection systematically across cases.

How Do Parties Really Choose?

Corbyn’s victory in 2015 was clear, but the process was keenly contested. Between them, three other candidates won nearly 40 per cent of the selectorate’s first-preference votes. Five years before, the same party—albeit with a rather different selectorate—had five candidates to choose between. That selection, too, was highly competitive, and was won by an extremely fine margin (Quinn 2012: 70).
Contrast that with the case of Martin Schulz, who was elected leader of the German Social Democrats in 2017. The 605 members of the party congress were unanimous in voting for him (Guardian 19 March 2017). Meanwhile, Swedish party congresses are almost always unanimous when they choose a new leader. How come? Because these selectorates, in fact, have little choice. Kenig, Rahat et al. (2015) show that in some European countries, including Austria, Germany, Hungary and Norway, a big majority of new leader selections involve such “coronations”, in which the decision-making body has, in effect, just one candidate to rubber stamp—a “ceremonial ratification” (Kenig, Rahat et al. 2015: 51).
What produces coronations, when other contests are so closely fought? Of course, it could be that there is only one eligible individual who wants the leader’s job. Yet that is surely rare, even in small parties. Politicians are not often associated with a reluctance to lead. Less far-fetched, perhaps, is that there is only one eligible individual who wants the job and thinks that she has a decent chance of landing it. In other words, some individuals who might have liked to be party leader nevertheless decline to take part in the selection process, because they would not win. Consider the case of the Swedish Liberal Party in 2019. A week before its congress was due to decide on a new leader, and after a rather heated campaign, three candidates still declared their interest in being chosen. By the time the congress convened, two had dropped out, and the favorite was duly elected unanimously (Svenska Dagbladet 29 June 2019).
Yet that raises all sorts of further questions. What is so bad about not winning? As any observer of American politics would attest, plenty of politicians with no realistic chance of success still run for their respective parties’ presidential nominations. They do this in order to raise certain political issues, elevate their personal profiles, attract some solid supporters, signal the existence of those supporters (especially to the eventual winner) and thus promote the candidates’ long-term political careers. Why does the same thing happen more rarely in European parties? Is there some mechanism by which some in a field of aspiring leaders infer that their continued candidacies are unwelcome? If so, what is that mechanism? To whom, exactly, within the party would a continued candidacy be unwelcome? Why does an aspiring candidate accept the signal? What sanction might she face if she did not?
Part of the answer is surely “culture”. It is probably not controversial to assert that a different “logic of appropriateness” (March and Olsen 1996) applies in one party compared to another. Some parties, for instance, have a stronger cus...

Table of contents

  1. Cover
  2. Front Matter
  3. 1. Conflicts and Coronations: Analysing Leader Selection in European Political Parties
  4. 2. Party Leadership Selection in Estonia: The Long-Lasting Authority of the “Founding Fathers”
  5. 3. Finland: Open and Public Contests Between Independent Candidates
  6. 4. The Selection of Party Leaders in Germany
  7. 5. Understanding How Political Parties In Europe Select Their Leaders: The Italian Case
  8. 6. Party Leadership Selection in Latvia: Divergent Practices of Precursory Delegation
  9. 7. From Coronation to Bear-Pit: Leadership Selection in the Party Order and Justice
  10. 8. How Political Parties Select Party Leaders in Poland: Party Leaders Decide and Party Members Endorse Their Decisions
  11. 9. The Rule of the Valberedning? Party Leader Selection in Sweden
  12. 10. Steer or No Steer? The Selection of Party Leaders in Britain
  13. 11. Patterns in Leader Selection: Where Does Power Lie?
  14. Back Matter