The Changing Role of Central Banks
eBook - ePub

The Changing Role of Central Banks

  1. English
  2. ePUB (mobile friendly)
  3. Available on iOS & Android
eBook - ePub

The Changing Role of Central Banks

Book details
Book preview
Table of contents
Citations

About This Book

The Changing Role of Central Banks derives lessons from current economic and financial challenges as well as failures in confronting them. Through this approach, it brings under perspective political and social reactions to major economic problems of the last ten years, particularly those pertaining to money and initiatives taken by central banks.

Frequently asked questions

Simply head over to the account section in settings and click on ā€œCancel Subscriptionā€ - itā€™s as simple as that. After you cancel, your membership will stay active for the remainder of the time youā€™ve paid for. Learn more here.
At the moment all of our mobile-responsive ePub books are available to download via the app. Most of our PDFs are also available to download and we're working on making the final remaining ones downloadable now. Learn more here.
Both plans give you full access to the library and all of Perlegoā€™s features. The only differences are the price and subscription period: With the annual plan youā€™ll save around 30% compared to 12 months on the monthly plan.
We are an online textbook subscription service, where you can get access to an entire online library for less than the price of a single book per month. With over 1 million books across 1000+ topics, weā€™ve got you covered! Learn more here.
Look out for the read-aloud symbol on your next book to see if you can listen to it. The read-aloud tool reads text aloud for you, highlighting the text as it is being read. You can pause it, speed it up and slow it down. Learn more here.
Yes, you can access The Changing Role of Central Banks by D. Chorafas in PDF and/or ePUB format, as well as other popular books in Economics & Economic Policy. We have over one million books available in our catalogue for you to explore.

Information

Year
2013
ISBN
9781137332288
1
Queen Elizabeth II and the Economists
1. Economic Theories Never Die. Maybe They Should.
On November 5, 2008, not quite two months after the Lehman Brothers bankruptcy and the Western economyā€™s descent to the abyss, Queen Elizabeth II inaugurated a new building at the London School of Economics. Referring to the financial crisis, she asked the professors: ā€œWhy did nobody notice it?ā€ The faculty was caught off guard. Among prominent apologies, the Queen received a letter signed by renowned British economists stating:
In summary, extent and severity of the crisis and to head it off, while it had many causes, was principally a failure of the collective imagination of many bright people, both in this country and internationally, to understand the risks to the system as a whole.1
If it were a failure of collective imagination, then its origin can be easily found in the tunnel vision of economists following different schools, whose masters are long dead, and the problems they faced, which were quite different from current realities. Though old recipes donā€™t necessarily apply, still the large majority of todayā€™s economics experts think in ā€œold schoolā€ terms because they have been trained in different theories whose time is past. Therefore, it comes as no surprise that when they adopt their modus vivendi, they choose from:
ā€¢Monetarist theories,
ā€¢The Austrian School,
ā€¢Keynesian theories, and
ā€¢Marxist manifestos.2
These are passing theories, not universal laws. According to Mao Zedong: ā€œA universal law has a predictive value which asserts the certain existence of the phenomenon described by that law in instances as yet unobserved. The universal law thus draws attention to, and guides analysis of the phenomenon . . . (while) the particular law would be revealed by an empirical investigation informed by the knowledge of the relevant universal law.3
The man who rebuilt the devastated Chinese economy from scratch proved to be a successful practical economist,4 deriving his know-how from what he described as theory-practice-theory. Practice validated an existing theory, or led to a new one after having demolished the old. This is exemplified by Maoā€™s famous quotation that ā€œthere is no construction without destruction,ā€ words evoking the ancient Chinese philosophy of yin and yang, of flowing and damming.
Not only the economy but science also is built on these premises. However, unlike theories in physics, where even the most beautiful ones are disregarded because of a new ā€œnasty fact,ā€ theories in economics linger on even if they have been disproved by extreme failure, like communism in Russia. It is as if, like old soldiers, economic theories never die, because economists have not been taught:
ā€¢How to integrate the lessons of political history with those of economics,
ā€¢How to think ā€œout of the box,ā€ and
ā€¢How to apply practical, not theoretical, solutions to emerging problems.
The truth behind these three bullets has been indirectly confirmed by the letter the British economists wrote to Queen Elizabeth II, including the ā€œmea culpa.ā€ Not only failure of collective imagination but also inertia is to blame. In early May 2012, Mervyn King, governor of the Bank of England, admitted he should have ā€œshouted from the rooftopsā€ about the risks that were building up in the financial system before the crash of 2008,5 but he did not.
The financial risks of 2007 and 2008 had practically no precedents and therefore they could be addressed by none of the existing economic theories. Instead, they provide the new evidence, the ā€œnasty factā€ that demolishes theories. To better understand this argument, the reader should appreciate that both in economics and in physics, existing theories have this in common: Contrary to what many people think, their proof is not in their reasoning; it is in the results they produce when applied.6 Down to basics, theories are concepts in the form of tentative statements and, as such, they fail to provide the linkage:
ā€¢Between what is theoretical and what is practical, and
ā€¢Between creation of wealth and exercise of power.
These and other shortcomings arise from the fact that today economics is taught without its historical background and without a close connection to politics.7 The result is economic theories in a vacuum, with deliverables that are neither realistic nor a good guide to reasoning when confronted by novel, unprecedented, and acute conditions.
Economic history is fundamental to understanding what is going on now, and politics brings realism into economics since the two work in unison; keeping them apart makes no sense. Beyond this lies the fact that if history and politics are kept out of the picture, then what is left of the science of economics can only show what has happened on the surfaceā€”even if the most important events are to be found at the root of the problem. Study the past, Confucius said, if you care about the future.
In every catastrophe there exists an original sin for which, usually, there is more than one reason but very often (albeit not always) the key factor is political. For instance, failure on the part of politicians to answer the call of duty when the economic scales tip over, accompanied by a search for easy solutions, loose monetary policy, and regulatory laxity.
Disinterest by common citizen in protecting their longer-term interests, leading them to wrong-way thinking; for instance, that entitlements (like diamonds) are forever. These are issues that the present-day crisis in Europe and in America has put squarely on the table, and they need both deeper and wider analysis than is available now.
Here is an example of superficial reasoning. In late 2011, the University of Chicago asked 40 renowned economists, including some short-listed for the Nobel Prize, if they agreed that the outcome in price stability and employment would be better for the average American if the dollar was tied to gold. Each one of them disagreed with this hypothesis.
When asked to explain their position, many of the economists stated that the volatility in the supply and the price of gold make it an unreliable anchor.8 This one-sided vision totally ignored the fact that the balance sheets of four major Western central banksā€”Federal Reserve, Bank of England, European Central Bank, and Swiss National Bankā€”have tripled, and in one case quintupled, within a short span of four years (2008ā€“2012). Is printed money a stable anchor?
Critics say that another reason for worrying about ā€œestablishedā€ economic theories is that they are constantly interpreted and misinterpreted as a large number of economists today base their judgment on a relatively short subjective experience. As a result, there may well be levels of reasoning, as well as realities and truths, in economic events that are missed.
In many cases, while helpful, our common sense9 falls short of revealing the total picture that could guide us to a better understanding of current events and predicting future events. To this are added misconceptions often originating in personal bias as well as in confused directives ā€œfrom aboveā€:
ā€¢ā€œSpend, donā€™t save,ā€ say the governments of Western countries as their economies hover between sluggish recovery and recession.
ā€¢ā€œSave,ā€ say the same governments as they contemplate the need for savings to finance public projects, confront the aging of their populations, and ease the growing strain of paying pensions as well as paying for health care and other entitlements.
Victory belongs to him who successfully confronts the challenge, said Arnold J. Toynbee, the historian. We confront our challenges neither by ā€œfailures of collective imaginationā€ nor by making contradictory statements and giving confused directives. If we plant sick trees, then we reap bitter fruits, Mao has said.
2. The Economic and Social Future Is Uncertain
The economists responding to the Queenā€™s query should have informed the sovereign that one of the worst fallacies in the last three decades has been the widely shared belief that America, Britain, and Eurolandā€™s member states are ā€œrich nations.ā€ For Britain and France, this was true prior to World War I, but it became questionable between the two world wars and is a bogus statement today. As for America, its economic might at the end of World War II has been eroded by successive governments and their handouts.
Riches come and go, particularly when they are badly managed. In 2012 no Western nation could call itself ā€œrich.ā€ Western resources are largely depleted; with few exceptions, the budgets of Western sovereigns are in the red and the current accounts of many are negative. Even if among its citizens ā€œthisā€ or ā€œthatā€ jurisdiction counts billionaires,10 household wealth has taken a beatingā€”and so did the common citizenā€™s standard of living.11
The recent case of an industrial countryā€™s rise and fall is revealing. For three decades, 1960s through 1980s, Japan was Asiaā€™s economic miracle, its richest and most powerful economy. It was the first Asian nation to industrialize but the emerging Asian tigersā€”Hong Kong, Singapore, South Korea, Thailand, Malaysia, and Taiwanā€”followed in Japanā€™s tracks and by 1990 Japanā€™s highly leveraged economy lost its might and fell out of gear as its banking and real estate sectors imploded.
Chinaā€™s economy, which was tiny during the same period, is now bigger than Japanā€™s and aims to become the no 1 economy in the world before 2020. In terms of purchasing-power-parity (PPP) in 2012, GDPs per person in Singapore, Hong Kong, Taiwan (in that order), and, more recently, in South Korea, are ahead of Japanā€™s. Singapore with $70,000 per person, and Hong Kong with $60,000, have left Japan and its $40,000 GDP per capita in the dust.
No existing economic theory reflects this rapid turnaround and its dramatic aftereffects. Therefore, the faculty of the London School of Economics should have informed the Queen that the nineteenth-century economic theories have been shaken to the ground by their shortcomings, their failures, and the fact that the premises on which they rest are no longer believable. Society has changed, and not only in moving away from the work ethic.
ā€¢In the preā€“World War II years and for nearly three decades after the war, the West had a working societyā€”a sociĆ©tĆ© de travail, as the French call it.
ā€¢But ...

Table of contents

  1. Cover
  2. Title
  3. Prologue
  4. 1 Queen Elizabeth II and the Economists
  5. 2 Money
  6. 3 Monetary Policy
  7. 4 Currency Exchange in a Globalized World
  8. 5 Preserving the Value of Money
  9. 6 Central Banks Are Reserve Institutions, Not Firefighters
  10. 7 The Challenge of Bank Regulation
  11. 8 Loose Ends of Bank Supervision and Regulation
  12. 9 Counterparty Risk, Data Points, and CDSs
  13. Epilogue
  14. Notes
  15. Index