The Politics of Regulation in the UK
eBook - ePub

The Politics of Regulation in the UK

Between Tradition, Contingency and Crisis

  1. English
  2. ePUB (mobile friendly)
  3. Available on iOS & Android
eBook - ePub

The Politics of Regulation in the UK

Between Tradition, Contingency and Crisis

Book details
Book preview
Table of contents
Citations

About This Book

This book explores the discourse of regulatory crisis in the UK and examines why, despite the increasing contestation of the principles underpinning the regulatory state, its institutions and practices continue to be firmly embedded within the governance of the British state. It considers its implications for our understanding of the contemporary nature of the British state, and to the study of regulation which is no longer confined to the domain of low politics, populated by technocrats, but is scrutinised by elected politicians, and the subject of the front pages rather than the financial pages. The author sets the British regulatory tradition in a wider context, both spatially, in terms of the challenges presented by Europeanisation, and temporally, critically analysing the process of crisis construction in the narratives of neoliberalism and participatory democracy in the contemporary era.

Frequently asked questions

Simply head over to the account section in settings and click on “Cancel Subscription” - it’s as simple as that. After you cancel, your membership will stay active for the remainder of the time you’ve paid for. Learn more here.
At the moment all of our mobile-responsive ePub books are available to download via the app. Most of our PDFs are also available to download and we're working on making the final remaining ones downloadable now. Learn more here.
Both plans give you full access to the library and all of Perlego’s features. The only differences are the price and subscription period: With the annual plan you’ll save around 30% compared to 12 months on the monthly plan.
We are an online textbook subscription service, where you can get access to an entire online library for less than the price of a single book per month. With over 1 million books across 1000+ topics, we’ve got you covered! Learn more here.
Look out for the read-aloud symbol on your next book to see if you can listen to it. The read-aloud tool reads text aloud for you, highlighting the text as it is being read. You can pause it, speed it up and slow it down. Learn more here.
Yes, you can access The Politics of Regulation in the UK by Daniel Fitzpatrick in PDF and/or ePUB format, as well as other popular books in Politik & Internationale Beziehungen & Europäische Politik. We have over one million books available in our catalogue for you to explore.

Information

Part I
Political and Regulatory Traditions
© The Author(s) 2016
Daniel FitzpatrickThe Politics of Regulation in the UKUnderstanding Governance10.1057/978-1-137-46199-5_1
Begin Abstract

1. Introduction: The Politics of Tradition

Daniel Fitzpatrick1
(1)
Department of Politics, University of Manchester, Manchester, UK
End Abstract

Introduction

On 3 August 2015, former UBS and Citigroup trader Tom Hayes was sentenced to 14 years in HM Prison Wandsworth for his key role in the rigging of the London Interbank Offered Rate (Libor). Hayes was found guilty of eight counts of conspiracy to defraud with respect to the Libor fixing scandal. In sentencing him, Mr Justice Cooke said that the tariff imposed was designed to send a message:
to the world of banking [that] … The conduct involved here must be marked out as dishonest and wrong … The fact that others were doing the same as you is no excuse, nor is the fact that your immediate managers saw the benefit of what you were doing and condoned it and embraced it, if not encouraged it.
The prosecution of Hayes is an outlier in the normal operation of UK regulation. Historically, regulation in Britain has tended to emphasise informal ‘cooperation between insiders, rather than of open adversarial conflict’ (Moran 2003: 35). Regulators in Britain have traditionally shied away from the strict imposition of enforcement and sanctions, favouring strategies of persuasion and education instead (Vogel 1986). This culture of cooperation is premised on the Victorian ideal of the gentleman. This is the notion that ‘economic actors were gentlemen, with claims to a particular style of treatment by regulators, and with claims to gentlemanly standards that could deliver effective regulation without adversarial controls’ (Moran 2003: 43). This ‘gentlemanly ideal’ gave rise to a regulatory approach that emphasised conciliation and cooperation with powerful interests in industry, the City and the professions in the nineteenth century. The consolidation of the overarching approach and style of regulation came to form the British regulatory tradition.
In this context, the prosecution of Tom Hayes is notable for three reasons. The first is the relative novelty of someone receiving a criminal (let alone custodial conviction) for a corporate or financial crime. In the conventional view, the vast majority of corporate illegality is not considered to constitute ‘real’ crime (Tombs 2015). Indeed, Hayes himself admitted that during the initial investigation by the UK’s Serious Fraud Office: ‘I didn’t think about innocence or guilt.’ Second, the trial exposed the degree to which the game of financial capitalism is, in reality, rigged. The Libor serves an important benchmark standard that is relied upon as a reference for financial contracts, including mortgages and student loans, worth over $300 trillion. The Libor fixing scandal contradicts the narrative that the maladies of the financial system are invariably due to high risk-taking behaviour of a few rogue traders, rather than systematic greed and malfeasance. According to this view, any emboldening of regulation or enforcement must be weighed up against the costs of ‘stricter liability … Discouraging risk-taking altogether, in short, can be counterproductive’ (The Economist 2013). The Libor scandal (and the rigging of its Euro and Tokyo equivalents) demonstrated that, in practice, capital ‘does not operate or seek to operate according to free market principles … Despite paying lip-service … to the virtues of competition, it is not a discipline that all but a few business are willing to accept’ (Clarke 2000: 39).
At the same time, the scandal of Libor—a self-selected, self-policing committee of the world’s largest banks—also evidenced the extent to which the financial system still operates according to the subjective judgement and tacit knowledge of insiders in private ‘club worlds’. While these private domains are now transnational, the prevailing world-view of this contemporary elite would be familiar to an observer of nineteenth-century high finance. The prosecution of Hayes, therefore, highlights the anachronism of a regulatory system that remains largely predicated on a Victorian notion of gentlemanly capitalism. To what extent is this tradition of regulation still relevant in the current era of crisis?
The concept of tradition is at the core of this book. The term tradition, derived from the Latin verb tradere, means to ‘hand down’ (Young 1988: 95). Tradition denotes ‘crystallisations of the past which remain in the present’ via our forebears (Young 1988: 142; Shils 2006: 12; Finlayson 2003: 664). The different manifestations of tradition are abundant, encompassing both the material—such as physical artefacts, paintings, landscapes and buildings—and the ideational, pertaining to systems of beliefs and values. Traditions are realised and reproduced through human action, via the repetition, interpretation and elaboration of practices and institutions. The concept of tradition, therefore, does leave room for agency: only living and knowing human beings can enact, reproduce, and modify traditions (Shils 2006). It is not the ‘concrete actions’ of procedures and institutions that are transmitted but the ‘images of actions which they imply or present and the beliefs requiring, recommending, regulating, permitting, or prohibiting the re-enactment of those patterns’ (Shils 2006: 12).
The reproduction of tradition, however, can be unconscious as well as intentional: ‘Those who accept a tradition need not call it a tradition; its acceptability might be self-evident to them’ (Shils 2006: 13). Nor it is necessary to assume that actors adhere to a tradition on the basis that it has a longer lineage. Shils (2006: 13) argues that although this ‘quality of pastness’ is a common feature of tradition, some traditions are simply taken for granted and acquire what March and Olsen (2004) call the ‘logic of appropriateness’.
The concept of tradition is vital, therefore, to our understanding of change and continuity in the nature of politics and institutions. As Shils (2006: 328) points out: ‘The connection that binds a society to its past can never die out completely; it is inherent in the nature of society.’ Tradition is manifested in much practical continuity—such as the family, places, institutions, language—that are directly experienced in everyday life (Williams 1977: 116). In focusing on remnants of the past, tradition is often used interchangeably, in both everyday language and academic text, with both habit and custom. Hobsbawm and Ranger (2012: 2), however, point out that it is important not to conflate tradition with the notions of habit and custom. Tradition is distinguishable from habit, routine or convention because these are behaviours that have a personal quality, whereas tradition is always collective: ‘individuals can have their own rituals, but traditions as such are group properties’ (Giddens and Pierson 1998: 128). Custom, though referring to a pattern of repeated social behaviour, lacks the ‘extra measure of social inertia’ that tradition involves (Young 1988: 96). Hobsbawm (1983: 3) argues that:
the past, real or invented, to which … [traditions] refer, imposes fixed (normally formalized) practices, such as repetition. Custom in traditional societies has the double function of motor and fly wheel. It does not preclude innovation and change up to a point, though evidently the requirement that it must appear compatible or identical with precedent imposes substantial limitations on it.
It is important to recognise, however, that traditions are a source change, as well as continuity. It has been claimed that tradition is predisposed to continuity: ‘It is a version of the past which is intended to connect and ratify the present’ (Williams 1977: 116) and therefore ‘makes for inertia and acceptance rather than pressure and conflict’ (Miliband 1982: 2). In this sense, tradition can be seen as an intermediary between individuals and institutions, which creates a relationship between the past and the present (Popper 2014: 179–180). In offering ‘ready-made solutions to problems’ traditions constrain, whether consciously or unconsciously, the actions of individuals (Sztompka 1993: 65). The continuity of traditional political institutions and practice also reinforce a sense of national identity. As Rothman (cited in Rose 1990: 20) observes:
The development of British social and political life has involved a uniquely British synthesis of traditional patterns and the forces that transformed them. The synthesis was possible not only because traditional British society was less ‘sticky’ than its counterpart elsewhere, but because its patterns had taken on a national form before their transformation began. The result has been an organic community with its own peculiar political institutions. No wonder … the British tend to regard their institutions as peculiarly their own, while both Americans and Frenchmen identify themselves with universal ideas applicable to all peoples.
Traditions, however, are not static and frozen in time, but ‘living’ phenomena (Williams 1977: 117) that are reproduced through the interpretations and actions of individuals. Traditions are often the subject of questioning and reflection in the light of current experience or directly challenged by alternative visions (Halpin et al. 1997: 6). As McAnulla claims, ‘traditions do not impel us to stick to the status quo, there are opportunities to either accept elements of tradition or disregard them and make adjustments’ (2007: 9). Traditions are thus a source of change as well as continuity:
they are modified when people select certain fragments of tradition for special emphasis and ignore others … they may disappear when objects are abandoned and ideas rejected or forgotten. Traditions may also be revitalized and reappear after long periods of decay. (Sztompka 1993: 61)
Although there is a general consensus concerning the ability of traditions to change, the question of why they change is contested in the social sciences. For some authors, the existence of multiple traditions makes the clash of competing ones inevitable (Sztompka 1993: 63). Examples of rival or competing traditions are numerous and include: colonial and indigenous traditions; the traditions of different social classes; and regional traditions and sectarian traditions. Sztompka (1993: 63) argues that the mutual clash, or more rarely the mutual support, of traditions invariably influences the content of both in a dialectical (Socratic) fashion. Halpin et al. (1997: 6), for example, highlight the conflict and reciprocal effect between the meritocratic tradition, which justifies the retention of private education and grammar schools, and the egalitarian tradition, championed by supporters of non-selective comprehensive schools, within the British education system. Tant (1993), in the context of the British political system, analyses the interplay between the dominant elitist tradition and challenges originating from a participatory, democratic tradition. For others, the source of change is a Hegelian internal dialectic of contradictory elements within the same tradition. Williams (1977: 121–123), writing from a Marxist perspective, emphasises the dynamic interplay between the dominant and the potentially challenging ‘residual’ elements of a single tradition. Likewise, Greenleaf (1983a, b) argues that conflicting libertarian and collectivist aspects comprise an internal dialectic within British politics.
The existence of traditions in British politics is tacitly accepted. In the study of British politics, as well as other social science disciplines, the notion of tradition is often invoked to describe or explain events or historical legacies and to argue in favour of a desired set of social or political goods. The concept of tradition can be descriptive, detailing ‘the way we do stuff’ (Finlayson 2003: 664), explanatory as ‘an actively shaping force’ (Williams 1977: 115) and normative, ‘in that they are intended to influence the conduct of the audience to which they are addressed’ (Shils 1981: 24). Tradition, therefore, can be used not only to demonstrate what is done but also to explain why it is done and what should or ought to be done (Halpin et al. 1997: 5; MacIntyre 1984).
Whilst the centrality of tradition to political analysis is recognised, it is invariably undertheorised. The intuitive appeal of traditions has led to a tendency to view them as uncontested. As such, the impact of traditions on British politics and governance is underexplored. This is not to suggest that the concept of tradition is novel in political analysis. A diverse range of authors, employing various methodological and normative perspectives, have appealed to the role of traditions in their analysis of British politics (Hall 2011).
Much of the discussion in the UK has centred on the existence of a dominant governing paradigm and political culture referred to as the British political tradition (BPT). However, the notion of tradition is invaria...

Table of contents

  1. Cover
  2. Frontmatter
  3. 1. Political and Regulatory Traditions
  4. 2. Pressures for Change
  5. Backmatter