Economics of a Crowded Planet
eBook - ePub

Economics of a Crowded Planet

  1. English
  2. ePUB (mobile friendly)
  3. Available on iOS & Android
eBook - ePub

Economics of a Crowded Planet

Book details
Book preview
Table of contents
Citations

About This Book

This book asks the question, how would economics look today and into the future if one started with a blank sheet of paper? Written mainly for a technical audience, yet accessible to the lay reader, Economics of a Crowded Planet addresses the ontology, epistemology and methodology of a future economics as if from outside the economy looking in.It presents a conceptual framework for a future economics drawing from systems science and hierarchy theory, integrating central concepts from present-day economics, so as to orient the field in a direction that can serve society's future needs in practical ways.

The exposition reveals a paradigm called'market planetarianism ': the idea that the power of markets may be used to steer the economy toward a desired long-term goal. Both a prescriptive doctrine and an economic methodology, it treats the economy and nature as instances of complex, evolutionary systems, demanding analytical tools quiteunlike those of the 20 th -century mainstream.

Frequently asked questions

Simply head over to the account section in settings and click on “Cancel Subscription” - it’s as simple as that. After you cancel, your membership will stay active for the remainder of the time you’ve paid for. Learn more here.
At the moment all of our mobile-responsive ePub books are available to download via the app. Most of our PDFs are also available to download and we're working on making the final remaining ones downloadable now. Learn more here.
Both plans give you full access to the library and all of Perlego’s features. The only differences are the price and subscription period: With the annual plan you’ll save around 30% compared to 12 months on the monthly plan.
We are an online textbook subscription service, where you can get access to an entire online library for less than the price of a single book per month. With over 1 million books across 1000+ topics, we’ve got you covered! Learn more here.
Look out for the read-aloud symbol on your next book to see if you can listen to it. The read-aloud tool reads text aloud for you, highlighting the text as it is being read. You can pause it, speed it up and slow it down. Learn more here.
Yes, you can access Economics of a Crowded Planet by Fraser Murison Smith in PDF and/or ePUB format, as well as other popular books in Economics & Environmental Economics. We have over one million books available in our catalogue for you to explore.

Information

Year
2019
ISBN
9783030317980
© The Author(s) 2019
F. Murison SmithEconomics of a Crowded Planethttps://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-31798-0_1
Begin Abstract

1. Introduction

Fraser Murison Smith1
(1)
San Rafael, CA, USA
Fraser Murison Smith
End Abstract
This book frames an economics of a crowded planet as the study of a materially large economy in stable alignment with nature and as the engine of economic policy. That economics is compared and contrasted with the current state of the field as it exists early in the twenty-first century. The book concludes with a discussion of ways economics might evolve from here to there. The set of ideas that emerges from this discussion is tentatively labeled ‘market planetarianism’ for reasons to be discussed. A formal theory of market planetarianism remains an opportunity for future development.
The perspective is deliberately from outside the economy looking in. It is from the point of view of the whole planet as a unitary entity, as distinct from the social perspective, which by definition is from the inside, occasionally looking out.

Is Planet Earth Finite or Are Resources Unlimited?

The appearance of a large human economy on planet Earth was so sudden on natural timescales that it appeared like a chemical state-change. Over the past ten thousand years, Earth’s biota has undergone significant changes due to the spread of people, but humanity’s appropriation of natural resources and its discharge of wastes—its material intensity—has increased by orders of magnitude only within the last thousand years or so.1
One of the great misunderstandings between natural scientists and economists has revolved around the question of whether resources for the economy are limited. This question has arisen during the last few decades when it became apparent that the economy was becoming globally interconnected, both internally and with major planetary processes. The misunderstanding is significant because it reveals parties’ distinct ways of thinking about the economy and nature.
Early human societies considered resources finite. They lived directly off natural resources, whose abundance was limited by solar flux. Hunter-gatherers and early agricultural societies understood the perils of taking more at any one time than nature could offer. As society diversified, however, an increasing number of people no longer lived directly off the land. This physical dissociation from nature sowed the seeds for a psychological one. In Europe during the so-called ‘Renaissance,’ the psychological dissociation evolved into a presumption of dominance over nature. At that time, the global population and its total material intensity still were relatively small. The world seemed vast, and natural resources effectively limitless.
Then, late in the eighteenth century, the economy began to industrialize. It began living off stored solar flux in the form of fossil fuels. The population swelled as living standards improved. Material throughput mushroomed. It did not take long for some, whose profession was to study the natural world, to raise concerns about the growing material intensity of economic activity. Some authors have recently begun to refer to this new resource-intense era as the ‘Anthropocene’: an evolutionary period in which for the first time the activities of a single species—human beings—have measurable effects upon natural processes.2
Natural scientists measure such processes in terms of physical quantities: mass, velocity and pressure, for instance. To the natural scientist, planet Earth is finite, in a strictly material sense. It is materially closed, because all available material for human use is contained on Earth, the odd meteorite notwithstanding. Yet Earth is energetically open, receiving a constant flow of energy from the sun. If the economy ingests ever more stuff from nature, and ejects ever greater amounts of effluent back to nature, then this becomes a problem. It is not a sustainable enterprise. Not only are fundamental material limits in place but also Earth’s physical and biological systems form a complex of human life-support, which, if sufficiently destabilized, could bring societal collapse.
Economists, traditionally, study human choice. They measure preferences and values, which are nonmaterial measures. Since the economy incorporates a circulation of money, this money represents a convenient proxy for many kinds of value. To the economist, industrialization is a triumph of human technology. It adds value to the economy and increases living standards. If the scale of material intensity presents a long-term problem to the economy then, the conventional economist argues, the very technological brilliance that gave us industrialization in the first place surely can solve that problem as well. Provided the incentives operating within the economy are set up right, they will stimulate the necessary technological development.
Since Earth is materially closed, the resource-intensity problem can be solved if, and only if, it is vastly reduced. The conventional economic assumption of a triumph of technology therefore is a tacit admission of this fundamental biophysical limit. Resources for the economy may become ‘essentially unlimited’ only if technology enables the economy to recirculate them. Energy for this recirculation must come mostly from current solar flux; otherwise, given current technologies, there will be fuel wastes.
There is very little prior evidence to suggest that technology actually will triumph in redirecting resource flows within the economy rather than through it, although, as Chapter 2 mentions, some recent evidence points to an incipient decoupling of economic growth and material intensity. In any case, for a large economy on a crowded planet to persist within the confines of natural capacity, such technology will have to be developed.

What Is Economics For?

For much of the twentieth century, most economists steadfastly maintained that, as the science of choice, economics did not need to consider all the other messy, bothersome problems outside the study of markets. Specifically, if the economy as a whole was becoming embroiled in coevolution with natural systems, then it was not for the economist to address this coevolution but the policymaker. The economist could only advise the policymaker on the possible effects of any relevant legislation or regulation upon the markets.
That position is reasonable only in a world having a small economy, one materially insignificant relative to natural processes. In a large economy on a crowded planet, economics becomes a different kind of practice. This is because the purpose of the economy itself in such a world is no longer merely to serve consumer sovereignty but primarily to ensure its own persistence in long-term alignment with nature. The purpose of economics is inexplicably bound up with the assumed purpose of the economy. On a crowded planet, the scope, relevance and importance of economics expand to more closely resemble the original meaning of the term. The term ‘economics,’ came into use late in the nineteenth century as an outgrowth of the term ‘political economy’ originating with such early nineteenth-century authors as David Ricardo and John Stuart Mill. It has Greek roots: from oikonomia, whose parts are oikos for house and nomos for custom or law. Oikonomia is ‘how we run our house,’ or ‘housekeeping’ in modern parlance. ‘Economics’ came into use to describe the study of households’ allocation of scarce resources to satisfy wants. This etymological origin was understood all too well by former British prime minister Margaret Thatcher who, in defending her painful economic reforms of the early 1980s, referred to them as ‘good housekeeping.’
Two popular textbook definitions of economics during the twentieth century were provided by Lionel Robbins and Paul Samuelson. Robbins defined economics as “the science which studies human behavior as a relationship between ends and scarce means which have alternative uses.”3 Samuelson defined it as “how 
 we choose to use scarce productive resources with alternative uses, to meet prescribed ends
”4
These definitions are almost as widely held early in the twenty-first century as when they were coined. They are sufficiently broad to encompass just about any definition of ‘productive resources’ and ‘prescribed ends’. However, they may have arisen as a product of the particular, mechanical mathematics employed by early economists. As Nicholas Georgescu-Roegen argued, “any system that involves a conservation principle (given means) and a maximization rule (optimal satisfaction) is a mechanical analogue.”5 If a different kind of mathematics were employed to model the economy, such as one describing a historical trajectory through event-space, then it could have a profound effect upon the perceived identity and purpose of economics.
On a crowded planet, one having a high population, the end in question is the long-term persistence of the economy. That end sometimes might be at odds with an individual’s prescribed ends, unless that individual’s goal alsowere ‘harmony’ (however defined) with nature. The ‘productive resources’ in Samuels...

Table of contents

  1. Cover
  2. Front Matter
  3. 1. Introduction
  4. Part I. Coevolution of the Economy and Nature
  5. Part II. Where Is Economics Now?
  6. Part III. Where Does Economics Need to Be?
  7. Back Matter