Hayek: A Collaborative Biography
eBook - ePub

Hayek: A Collaborative Biography

Part XIV: Liberalism in the Classical Tradition: Orwell, Popper, Humboldt and Polanyi

  1. English
  2. ePUB (mobile friendly)
  3. Available on iOS & Android
eBook - ePub

Hayek: A Collaborative Biography

Part XIV: Liberalism in the Classical Tradition: Orwell, Popper, Humboldt and Polanyi

Book details
Book preview
Table of contents
Citations

About This Book

This latest volume in the Collaborative Biography of Hayek examines the interconnectednessbetween Hayek's (1944) The Road to Serfdom and George Orwell's Animal Farm (1945) and Nineteen Eighty-Four (1949); his relationship with Karl Popper and Karl Polanyi; and the workof Wilhelm von Humboldt. Mises had a 'deep emotional attachment' to the 'free' market andHayek believed that 'science' was driven by shallow emotions.
Hayek believed in 'democracy as a system of peaceful change of government; but that's allits whole advantage is, no other.' He felt democracy simply made it possible to get rid of thegovernment 'we' dislike. Hayek bemoaned the decay of superstition — the 'supporting moralbeliefs' – that are required to maintain 'our' civilization. Yet his Road to Serfdom neglected'another road to serfdom' – the possibility that there were multiple threats to individualfreedom –not just State power. In contrast, many other scholars and public intellectual warnedof the dangers of the concentration of power in institutions other than the State. Today thosefears have materialized in the guise of wealthy mega-corporations and billionaires whoseinfluence on government, on elections, on popular culture and on the dominant ideology, havebeen able to change the rules of the market in their favour – so that 'we' have now becometrapped in a new kind of serfdom. With contributions from a range of highly regarded scholars, this volume continues the Biography's rich exploration of Hayek's work and beliefs.

Frequently asked questions

Simply head over to the account section in settings and click on “Cancel Subscription” - it’s as simple as that. After you cancel, your membership will stay active for the remainder of the time you’ve paid for. Learn more here.
At the moment all of our mobile-responsive ePub books are available to download via the app. Most of our PDFs are also available to download and we're working on making the final remaining ones downloadable now. Learn more here.
Both plans give you full access to the library and all of Perlego’s features. The only differences are the price and subscription period: With the annual plan you’ll save around 30% compared to 12 months on the monthly plan.
We are an online textbook subscription service, where you can get access to an entire online library for less than the price of a single book per month. With over 1 million books across 1000+ topics, we’ve got you covered! Learn more here.
Look out for the read-aloud symbol on your next book to see if you can listen to it. The read-aloud tool reads text aloud for you, highlighting the text as it is being read. You can pause it, speed it up and slow it down. Learn more here.
Yes, you can access Hayek: A Collaborative Biography by Robert Leeson in PDF and/or ePUB format, as well as other popular books in Volkswirtschaftslehre & Wirtschaftstheorie. We have over one million books available in our catalogue for you to explore.

Information

Year
2018
ISBN
9783319944128
© The Author(s) 2018
Robert Leeson (ed.)Hayek: A Collaborative BiographyArchival Insights into the Evolution of Economicshttps://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-94412-8_1
Begin Abstract

1. ‘Property’ + ‘Aristocratic Dignity’ = ‘Scientific Glory’

Robert Leeson1, 2
(1)
Stanford University, Stanford, CA, USA
(2)
Notre Dame Australia University, Fremantle, WA, Australia
Robert Leeson

Keywords

OrwellHayekPopperThe role of the stateOro-liberalism
End Abstract
This Archival Insights into the Evolution of Economics series provides a systematic archival examination of the process by which economics is constructed and disseminated. All the major schools will be subject to critical scrutiny; a concluding volume will attempt to synthesize the insights into a unifying general theory of knowledge construction and influence. This volume—a sequel to Part VII, Hayek’s Encounters with Fifty Knowledge Communities—addresses Hayek’s (1899–1992) encounters with six influential individuals: George Orwell (1903–1950), Karl Popper (1902–1994), Wilhelm von Humboldt (1767–1835), Karl Polanyi (1886–1964), Walter Eucken (1891–1950), and (speculatively) Rudolf Steiner (1861–1925).
According to the second general editor of The Collected Works of F.A. Hayek, ‘Hayek was very, very careless about his references. Sometimes he would remember something but not remember it exactly, and sometimes would not go back and check. Every one of his quotations had to be double checked’ (Kresge 2013). But it was not scholarship that attracted disciples. As William Hutt explained: Ludwig ‘von’ Mises ‘was physically smaller than I had expected, but I was immediately struck by his really remarkable personality—a magnetism and tenacity created by his deep emotional attachment [emphasis added] to a free economy and the institutions on which it had to rely’ (cited by Egger 1999, 201). And according to Peter Boettke, Grove City’s Hans Sennholz—a ‘Misean for life’ Luftwaffe bomber pilot—‘doesn’t reach you with the technical aspects, but with the ideological aspects’ (cited by Doherty 2007, 423–424).
At the Koch-funded Austrian revival, ‘We were all converts already. It was more a forming of a clan’ (Blundell 2014, 102). Hayek (1978) told James Buchanan—the ‘George Mason Nobel Laureate’—that economic ‘science’ was driven by shallow emotions: ‘There’s no emotional disappointment in the other fields when you recognize that you can’t find out certain things; but so many hopes are tied up with the possible control and command over economic affairs that if a scientific study comes to the conclusion that it just can’t be done, people won’t accept it [emphasis added] for emotional reasons.’ 1 ‘Von’ Hayek advised Leo Rosten: ‘You can tell the people that our present constitutional order forces politicians to do things which are very stupid and which they know are very stupid 
 I want to make clear to the people [emphases added] that it’s what I call unlimited democracy which is the danger.’ 2
In Fascism versus Capitalism, Llewellyn Rockwell Jr. (2013, 96–98), the co-founder of the Ludwig von Mises Institute, described the process by which Hayek’s co-leader of the fourth generation leader of the Austrian School constructed ‘free’ market Truth:
The scene was recalled to me the way miracles are described in the Gospels 
 There is another respect in which we can all emulate Murray [Rothbard]. He was fearless in speaking the truth. He never let fear of colleagues, fear of the profession, fear of editors or political cultures, stand in the way of his desire to say what was true. This is why he turned to the Austrian tradition even though most economists at the time considered it a dead paradigm. This is why he embraced liberty, and worked to shore up its theoretical and practice rationale at a time when the rest of the academic world was going the other way 
 This fearlessness, courage, and heroism applied even in his political analysis.
According to Mises (1993 [1964], 36), Edwin Cannan (1861–1935) was ‘the last [emphasis added] in the long line of eminent British economists.’ The British Fascisti was established in 1923. Six years later, Hayek (1995 [1929], 68–70), while praising Cannan’s ‘fanatical conceptual clarity’ and his ‘kinship’ with Mises’ ‘crusade,’ noted that British-Austrians had failed to realize the necessary consequences of the whole system of Classical Liberal thought: ‘To be sure, it must be added at once [emphasis added] that Cannan by no means develops economic liberalism to its ultimate consequences with the same ruthless consistency as Mises.’ According to Bruce Caldwell (1995, 70, n67), Hayek was probably referring to Liberalism in the Classical Tradition in which Mises (1985 [1927], 19, 49) insisted that
The program of liberalism, therefore, if condensed into a single word, would have to read: property [Mises’ emphasis] 
 All the other demands of liberalism result from this fundamental demand 
 The victory of Fascism in a number of countries is only an episode in the long series of struggles over the problem of property.
Caldwell’s epigone-generation co-leader insists that Mises and Hayek had ‘intertwined research programs’: both were
advocates of the private property market order and attempts to dehomogenize Mises and Hayek on the issue of private property and knowledge are mistaken. (Boettke 2004)
Mises (2006a [1958], 94) noted that ‘Man is not a being that, on the one hand, has an economic side and, on the other hand, a political side, with no connection between the two.’ And as Boettke (2016) correctly pointed out: ‘Mises’s economics informed his political theory.’
The ‘Fascists’ that Mises (1985 [1927], 44, 49) praised included ‘Germans and Italians,’ ‘Ludendorff and Hitler.’ Mises aspired to provide intellectual leadership:
The great danger threatening domestic policy from the side of Fascism lies in its complete faith in the decisive power of violence. In order to assure success, one must be imbued with the will to victory and always proceed violently. This is its highest principle 
 The suppression of all opposition by sheer violence is a most unsuitable way to win adherents to one’s cause. Resort to naked force—that is, without justification in terms of intellectual arguments accepted by public opinion—merely gains new friends for those whom one is thereby trying to combat. In a battle between force and an idea, the latter always prevails. (emphases added) 3
Mises’ Second Estate insights about the power of ‘public opinion’ came almost a century after a similar discovery made by British aristocrats (see below); and somewhat belatedly, Mises discovered that Fascism was a conveyor belt along which Jews like himself had their property confiscated.
Four years after the demise of the Habsburgs, Mises (1922) denigrated the First Estate and their ‘evil seed’ of Christianity for having failed to protect the neo-feudal hierarchy. After the failure of his attempt to become the intellectual FĂŒhrer of a Nazi-Classical Liberal Pact (1985 [1927]), Mises sought a post-Hitler Pact with the American Religious Right, including public stoning theocrats (Leeson 2018a).
In May 1932, the prominent Nazi official, Gregor Strasser, declared that the ‘rise of National Socialism is the protest of a people against a State that denied the right to work and the revival of natural intercourse’ (cited by Bullock 1962, 215). The unemployment-inducing deflation that Mises and Hayek promoted facilitated Hitler’s 1933 rise to power and the subsequent advance of Soviet communism into the heart of Europe. Between 1933 and 1936, it also helped propagate both Keynesian economics and a distinctive Chicago monetary tradition (Leeson 2003a, b).
Joan Robinson (1979, 186) described her first meeting with Michal Kalecki in Cambridge in 1936 as a Pirandello play: Kalecki was ‘perfectly familiar with our brand new ideas and he had invented for himself some of Keynes’s fanciful concepts 
 I could not tell whether it was I who was speaking or he.’ So it was on the right. Hitler—a convert to Mises’ business cycle theory—declared: ‘Power comes at last in Germany only to him who has anchored this power most deeply in the people’ (cited by Bullock 1962, 245). In Human Action, ‘von’ Mises (1998 [1949], 188–189) again emphasized the importance of selling ideology to the ‘inferior’ sovereign consumers:
Might is the faculty or power of directing actions. As a rule one says only of a man or of groups of men that they are mighty. Then the definition of might is: might is the power to direct other people’s actions. He who is mighty, owes his might to an ideology. Only ideologies can convey to a man the power to influence other people’s choices and conduct. One can become a leader only if one is supported by an ideology which makes other people tractable and accommodating. Might is thus not a physical and tangible thing, but a moral and spiritual phenomenon. A king’s might rests upon the recognition of the monarchical ideology on the part of his subjects. He who uses his might to run the state, i.e., the social apparatus of coercion and compulsion, rules. Rule is the exercise of might in the political body. Rule is always based upon might, i.e., the power to direct other people’s actions. Of course, it is possible to establish a government upon the violent oppression of reluctant people. It is the characteristic mark of state and government that they apply violent coercion or the threat of it against those not prepared to yield voluntarily. Yet such violent oppression is no less founded upon ideological might. He who wants to apply violence needs the voluntary cooperation of some people. An individual entirely dependent on himself can never rule by means of physical ...

Table of contents

  1. Cover
  2. Front Matter
  3. 1. ‘Property’ + ‘Aristocratic Dignity’ = ‘Scientific Glory’
  4. 2. The ‘Free’ Market Use of (Ideological) ‘Knowledge’ in Society
  5. 3. Hayek and Humboldt on Freedom and the Role of the State
  6. 4. Hayek, Orwell, and the Road to Nineteen Eighty-Four?
  7. 5. Hayek and Popper’s Enchanting Personal and Professional Relationship
  8. 6. Hayek and Popper on Historicism, Hegel, and Totalitarian Regimes
  9. 7. Hayek and Popper on Piecemeal Engineering and Ordo-Liberalism
  10. 8. Karl Polanyi vs Friedrich von Hayek: The Socialist Calculation Debate and Beyond
  11. 9. Hayek’s Liberalism and Its Critics
  12. 10. Another Road to Serfdom
  13. 11. Triple Governance: Hayek’s Lost Thesis
  14. 12. Hayek, Austrian Business Cycle Theory, and The Fatal Conceit
  15. Back Matter