An Authentic Account of Adam Smith
eBook - ePub

An Authentic Account of Adam Smith

  1. English
  2. ePUB (mobile friendly)
  3. Available on iOS & Android
eBook - ePub

An Authentic Account of Adam Smith

Book details
Book preview
Table of contents
Citations

About This Book

This book is a textual criticism of modern ideas about the work of Adam Smith that offers a new perspective on many of his famous contributions to economic thought.Adam Smith is often hailed as a leading figure in the development of economic theories, but modern presentations of his works do not reflect Smith's actual ideas or influence during his lifetime.

Gavin Kennedy believes that Smith's name and legacy were often appropriated or made into myths in the 19th and 20th centuries, with many misconceptions persisting today. Offering new analysis of works on rhetoric, moral sentiments, jurisprudence, the invisible hand, The Wealth of Nations, and Smith's very private views on religion, the book gives a new perspective on this important canonical thinker

Frequently asked questions

Simply head over to the account section in settings and click on ā€œCancel Subscriptionā€ - itā€™s as simple as that. After you cancel, your membership will stay active for the remainder of the time youā€™ve paid for. Learn more here.
At the moment all of our mobile-responsive ePub books are available to download via the app. Most of our PDFs are also available to download and we're working on making the final remaining ones downloadable now. Learn more here.
Both plans give you full access to the library and all of Perlegoā€™s features. The only differences are the price and subscription period: With the annual plan youā€™ll save around 30% compared to 12 months on the monthly plan.
We are an online textbook subscription service, where you can get access to an entire online library for less than the price of a single book per month. With over 1 million books across 1000+ topics, weā€™ve got you covered! Learn more here.
Look out for the read-aloud symbol on your next book to see if you can listen to it. The read-aloud tool reads text aloud for you, highlighting the text as it is being read. You can pause it, speed it up and slow it down. Learn more here.
Yes, you can access An Authentic Account of Adam Smith by Gavin Kennedy in PDF and/or ePUB format, as well as other popular books in Economics & Economic Theory. We have over one million books available in our catalogue for you to explore.

Information

Year
2018
ISBN
9783319638027
Ā© The Author(s) 2017
Gavin KennedyAn Authentic Account of Adam Smithhttps://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-63802-7_5
Begin Abstract

Adam Smith and the ā€˜Invisible Handā€™

Gavin Kennedy1
(1)
Edinburgh, UK
Gavin Kennedy
End Abstract
***

Introduction

Multiple references to Adam Smithā€™s use and supposed meaning of the 2-word metaphor of ā€˜an Invisible Handā€™ today stand in stark contrast to the almost total absence of mentions of the same metaphor whilst Smith was alive and for many decades after he died in 1790. Contemporary sources such as the Monthly Review (1776) did not mention the ā€˜Invisible Handā€™ and nor did his contemporary critic, Governor Pownall, September 1776, mention the ā€˜Invisible Handā€™ in his long and detailed critique of the Wealth of Nations. 1
Significantly, ā€˜the Invisible Handā€™ only became a subject for academic discussion very slowly, from a few mentions in the 1870s in very limited circulations, until the mid-twentieth century. There may have been unrecorded oral mentions of which to date we have had no access. However, from the 1960s mentions of the ā€˜Invisible Handā€™ rapidly grew both in academic and public or media discourse, until mentions became ubiquitous from the 1970s. They remain ubiquitous in 2017.
Exceptionally, Dugald Stewart, the son of Michael Stewart, a fellow student of Smithā€™s at Glasgow, and close family friend, referred to a theological version of the ā€˜Invisible Handā€™ of God in 1792. Dugald wrote:
he follows blindly his instinctive principles of action, [and] he is led by an Invisible Hand and contributes his share to the execution of a plan ā€¦even in those rude periods of society, when like the lower a animals, he followed blindly his instinctive principles of action, of the nature and advantages of which he has no conception (Stewart 1792).
We can on occasion read similar theological assertions linking the ā€˜Invisible Handā€™ to ā€˜a planā€™ even today. Of relevance to my general point, Dugald Stewart, published his own economics lectures verbatim that he delivered at Edinburgh University, which included extracts from Wealth of Nations in the form of long footnote quotations, relating to the topics he discussed in his own lectures. One of his extracts included the very paragraph containing Smithā€™s singular reference to ā€˜an Invisible Handā€™ in Wealth of Nations. Noticeably, Stewart focussed on that paragraphā€™s general economics content, and ignored Smithā€™s use of the ā€˜Invisible Handā€™ altogether. However, there is some concern, as expressed by Sir William Hamilton, Editor of the 1855 papers, that many pages of Dugaldā€™s relevant political economy manuscript papers were missing, believed destroyed by a member of his family, specifically his son, Col. Stewart, who reportedly suffered from a mental illness, and, therefore, the extant papers remain incomplete (Stewart 1855).
In a similar singular example, the ā€˜Invisible Handā€™ in Smithā€™s Wealth of Nations paragraph was paraphrased by Buckle, in 1859, without his commenting on the ā€˜Invisible Handā€™ metaphor itself.
After the 1870s there was a minor flurry of isolated mentions, literally by only a handful of authors, on Smithā€™s use of the ā€˜Invisible Handā€™, which was followed by long near silences, interrupted occasionally by individuals discussing Smithā€™s ā€˜Invisible Handā€™, such as by Frederick Maitland, a Lawyer, in a paper for his Cambridge Fellowship, who referred directly to the Invisible Hand. 2 Generally, Smithā€™s use of the now infamous metaphor, was hardly mentioned in either the academic or the popular press.
I found a singular exception in my collection of nineteenth-century editions of Smithā€™s Wealth Of Nations. It is in the 1891 edition of Wealth of Nations, edited by J. Shield Nicholson, Professor of Political Economy at Edinburgh University. Nicholson includes a 32-page Introductory Essay on WN. 3 On page 2 of his essay, Professor Nicholson, criticises ā€˜the prevailing error that Political Economy inculcates selfishnessā€™, and responds with Smithā€™s long-ignored paragraph that self-interest results in the ā€˜general benefit of societyā€™, and quotes: the merchant ā€˜generally, indeed, neither intends to promote the public interest nor knows how much he is promoting it ā€¦ and he is in this and many other cases, led by an Invisible Hand to promote an end which was no part of his intention.ā€™
Professor Nicholson, in the context of his quotation and his comments, clearly considered the ā€˜Invisible Handā€™ was a force of God and not a metaphoric literary device of Smithā€™s. However, the main point cannot pass unnoticed that Nicholsonā€™s direct reference to this passage was most unusual amongst authors after Smith died in 1790, until the 1870s.
There are a few other exceptions up to 1948, when the frequency of mentions of the ā€˜Invisible Handā€™ slowly accelerated until the late 1960s, when mentions of the ā€˜Invisible Handā€™ increased to become a veritable flood that still flows strongly.
Samuels, after completing 12-years of studying the role and use of the ā€˜Invisible Handā€™ in the worldā€™s economic literature, reported that ā€˜Incomplete data for materials published in the English language ā€“ principally, but not solely, economic writings ā€“ suggest that between 1816 and 1938, the average annual level of writings in which the ā€˜Invisible Handā€™ appeared was very low, confirming my assertions from my own library searches.
Thereafter, writes Samuels, from roughly 1942 through 1974, the average annual level of writings doubled; from 1975 through 1979, it roughly doubled again; and between 1980ā€“1989, it was approximately 6.5 times higher than it had been during 1942 through to 1974. Between 1990 and 1998, the average annual level was a little more than eight times that of the 1942ā€“1974 level and slightly more than 20 percent higher than the 1980-1989 level. During 2000-2006, the average annual level seems to have receded to a level slightly more than 60 per cent of the 1990ā€“1999 level, the highest level reached so far. 4
***
This chapter addresses this strange phenomenon of an apparent disinterest in Smithā€™s use of the ā€˜Invisible Handā€™ whilst he was alive and for long after his death in 1790, up to the 1870s. This was followed by an, albeit very slow beginning of cumulative mentions, then a slow acceleration after 1948, and finally a veritable stampede of widespread references from the mid-1970s onwards that continues on an even larger scale and in an ever wider-spread of in-depth acclaim across all media today, with abundant and varying versions of what the ā€˜Invisible Handā€™ supposedly means.
The idea of a theological ā€˜Invisible Handā€™ has a longer and deeper history than the secular use of it by Adam Smith. It has been in regular use in theological contexts since the seventeenth century (Harrison 2011).
There were various literary mentions of a ā€˜hidden handā€™ in fiction and they include, for example, its use by Sir Walter Scott, at the time, Scotlandā€™s leading historical author, in his novel, The Antiquary (1816). Scott paid homage to a then living artistā€™s framed painting on the wall of a fictional cottage in one of his stories. The named, living artist wrote to him, with the typical deferential modesty of the age, to say that Scottā€™s reference to his work had placed him under a ā€˜debt of obligationā€™, because by his mention of his ā€˜unseen hand in The Antiquary, you took me up, and claimed me, the humble painter of domestic sorrow, as your countrymanā€™.
Another isolated early mention was by the popular Scottish, charismatic Calvinist Presbyterrean preacher, Thomas Chalmers (1780ā€“1847), who in 1833, preached the ā€˜Invisible Handā€™ of God that ā€˜bespeaks of a master handā€™ that renders ā€˜the greatest economic goodā€¦by the spontaneous play and busy competition of many thousand wills, each bent on the prosecution of its own selfishnessā€™. 5 Chalmers wed his theology to his version of Adam Smithā€™s political economy, which appealed to his large evangelical congregations and readers of his several books in his heyday.
In contrast, leading political economists, such as David Ricardo, Jean-Baptiste Say, Thomas Robert Malthus, John Stuart Mill, Alfred Marshall, William Stanley Jevons and others, who read and commented in detail on Wealth of Nations and who published their comments on Adam Smithā€™s political economy widely, yet all maintained a manifest silence about Smithā€™s supposed crowning glory of ā€˜an Invisible Handā€™, thus implicitly crediting the metaphor with no great significance.
Typical of this group of specialists, who studied Adam Smithā€™s Wealth of Nations in depth, was J. R. McCulloch, who started publishing, the first of several editions of WN in 1828, laced with his comments, both critical and complimentary within Smithā€™s text and its 669 pages. His 3rd edition of his WN text was published in 1885. Given McCullochā€™s detailed comments on Smithā€™s text throughout WN, it is remarkable that McCulloch said not a word about Smithā€™s use of the ā€˜Invisible Handā€™ metaphor in the relevant passage in Book IV.2, p. 199. Moreover, there are 14 footnotes, some quite long ones, in this chapter alone, but none that relate to the famous metaphor, indicating how non-consequential contemporary readers regarded the ā€˜Invisible Handā€™ (Ramsay McCulloch 1872).
The long silence amongst leading political economists up to the 1770s contrasts with the assertions of most modern economists today, who consider Adam Smithā€™s use of the ā€˜Invisible Handā€™ to be two words of the highest significance in all of economics. These assertions and their related assumptions remain manifestly untrue. Yet today, judging by the evidence of the mass of economic publications across the world, the ā€˜Invisible Handā€™ currently enjoys the status of enormous significance for many economists. If the ā€˜Invisible Handā€™ metaphor had any degree of the significance that is attributed to it today, the fact of the absence of mentions of the now famous metaphor by Smithā€™s contemporaries, and those leading economists who came immediately after him, well into the late-nineteenth century, suggests the contrary view that the metaphor as used by Adam Smith was generally considered to be of little significance amongst major figures in the history of economic thought, and that this view was shared by Adam Smith himself.

Exhibit 3: Some General Theological References to ā€˜an Invisible Handā€™, from Ancient Times to the eighteenth-century:

1 Ovid: ā€˜his Invisible Hand, inflicting wound within woundā€™; (8 AD).
2 Lactantius,ā€™ his shoulder plunged the sword.writhā€™d his hand, deep in his breasts, made many wounds in oneā€™; invisibilisā€™ (250ā€“325 AD);
3 Augustine, City of God: ā€˜moves visible things by invisible meansā€™, (340ā€“430 AD);
4 Shakespeare, W, (1606): ā€˜Thy Bloody and Invisible Handā€™;
5 Glanvill, J. ā€˜nature by an Invisible Hand in all things; ā€˜invisible intellectual agentsā€™ (1661);
6 Voltaire (1718): ā€˜an Invisible Hand suspends above your headā€™;
7 Defoe, D: (1723) ā€˜A sudden Blow from an almost Invisible Handā€™, (1722);
8 Charles Rollin (1738) said of the Israeli Kings, ā€˜the Invisible Hand which conducted themā€™;
9 William Leechman (1755): ā€˜the unseen silent hand of an all wise providenceā€™;
10 Charles Bonnet, (1781): ā€˜led to its end by an Invisible Handā€™, in ā€˜Contemplations of de la Natureā€™;
11 Jean-Baptiste Robinet (1761): ā€˜basins of mineral water, prepared by an Invisible Handā€™ in De La natureā€™;
12 Walpole, H. 1764: ā€˜with violence by an Invisible Handā€™;
13 Reeve, C. (1778): ā€˜he was hurried away by an Invisible Handā€™.
William Leechman, Charles Bonnet, Jean-Baptiste Robinet, Walpole, and Reeve, were all contemporaries of Adam Smith, indicating their relatively widespread familiarity of references to an ā€˜Invisible Handā€™ in general literature. Yet none of them appear to have commented on Smithā€™s use of it.
Clearly, the ā€˜Invisible Handā€™ had a long history of its use by many others, primarily in theological contexts, before Smith used it ...

Table of contents

  1. Cover
  2. Front Matter
  3. Introduction
  4. How Adam Smith Learned to Bargain
  5. Adam Smith on Rhetoric and Perspicuity
  6. Adam Smith on Metaphors
  7. Adam Smith and the ā€˜Invisible Handā€™
  8. The Social Evolution of Jurisprudence
  9. Smithā€™s Wealth of Nations
  10. Smithā€™s Alleged Religiosity
  11. Back Matter