Airport Competition
  1. 462 pages
  2. English
  3. ePUB (mobile friendly)
  4. Available on iOS & Android
eBook - ePub
Book details
Book preview
Table of contents
Citations

About This Book

The break-up of BAA and the blocked takeover of Bratislava airport by the competing Vienna airport have brought the issue of airport competition to the top of the agenda for air transport policy in Europe. Airport Competition reviews the current state of the debate and asks whether airport competition is strong enough to effectively limit market power. It provides evidence on how travellers chose an airport, thereby altering its competitive position, and on how airports compete in different regions and markets. The book also discusses the main policy implications of mergers and subsidies.

Frequently asked questions

Simply head over to the account section in settings and click on ā€œCancel Subscriptionā€ - itā€™s as simple as that. After you cancel, your membership will stay active for the remainder of the time youā€™ve paid for. Learn more here.
At the moment all of our mobile-responsive ePub books are available to download via the app. Most of our PDFs are also available to download and we're working on making the final remaining ones downloadable now. Learn more here.
Both plans give you full access to the library and all of Perlegoā€™s features. The only differences are the price and subscription period: With the annual plan youā€™ll save around 30% compared to 12 months on the monthly plan.
We are an online textbook subscription service, where you can get access to an entire online library for less than the price of a single book per month. With over 1 million books across 1000+ topics, weā€™ve got you covered! Learn more here.
Look out for the read-aloud symbol on your next book to see if you can listen to it. The read-aloud tool reads text aloud for you, highlighting the text as it is being read. You can pause it, speed it up and slow it down. Learn more here.
Yes, you can access Airport Competition by David Gillen, Hans-Martin Niemeier, Peter Forsyth, Peter Forsyth, David Gillen, Jurgen Muller, Hans-Martin Niemeier in PDF and/or ePUB format, as well as other popular books in Technology & Engineering & Transportation & Navigation. We have over one million books available in our catalogue for you to explore.

Information

Chapter 1
Introduction and Overview

Peter Forsyth, David Gillen, JĆ¼rgen MĆ¼ller and Hans-Martin Niemeier
One of the themes in an earlier German Aviation Research Society (GARS) book, The Economic Regulation of Airports (Forsyth et al., 2004), was that ā€˜strong competition between airports is not feasibleā€™ (xxviii); we argued this might change in the future. That book raised, under the heading of future challenges, the ā€˜bigger question of whether, in more competitive circumstances, there is a continued need for formal price regulationā€™ (xxix). In this current book we take up the issue of airport competition, with particular reference to Europe. We explore whether and where it exists, how strong it is and what policy implications it has.
Since the publication of the earlier book, developments have amplified the challenges and have put them on top of the agenda of airport policy in some jurisdictions. Three events stand out: the proposed break-up of BAA, the blocked takeover of Bratislava Airport by Vienna Airport and the prohibition of subsidies to Ryanair by Brussels South Charleroi Airport.
In 2008, the UK Competition Commission recommended that BAA be forced to divest itself of two of its three London airports, and to sell either Glasgow or Edinburgh Airport. The stated objective is to promote competition between the airports.
ā€¢ On 18 October 2006 the Slovak government made a final decision to stop the sale of Bratislava Airport to neighbouring Vienna Airport because it had not been approved by the Slovenian anti-monopoly office. This case is similar to the BAA case, but it raises some additional issues. There was a concern that Bratislava Airport had the potential to compete with Vienna Airport, at least in some markets.
ā€¢ On 3 February 2004 the European Commission prohibited direct aid granted by the Walloon Region and Brussels South Charleroi Airport to Ryanair. Ryanair appealed this decision and were successful in having the case overturned; a decision by the European Court of First Instance (2008) in December 2008. Nonetheless, the issue of state subsidies to low-cost carrier (LCC) airports, as well as to major airports served by full-service airlines, has remained a contentious issue. For example, Ryanair has complained to the European Commission about state aid of over ā‚¬400 million per annum to Schiphol Airport and to KLM/Air France. The Charleroi decision involves a horizontal aspect of competition among airports, along with a vertical aspect of how distortions of airport competition affect competition between airlines in the downstream market.
The case for regulation of airports comes about because of a lack of competition between airports, and their consequent possession and use of market power. This lack of competition may come about for two types of reason: locational reasons and natural monopoly reasons.
The locational explanation argues that for most airports there are no close substitutes as attractive locations are limited (Forsyth, 1997). It is very difficult to obtain permission to build airports in cities with existing airports, for example, to build a competing airport next to hubs like Frankfurt or Paris airports. Such airports have a de facto monopoly reflecting planning and environmental restrictions and they have market power in the provision of aviation services which suggests a case for regulation.
The other explanation relies on economies of scale in airport provision. Thus, a monopoly is efficient as two or more airports would lead to higher average costs. If there is more than one airport, and competition is present between the airports, this competition will break down, since the airport which is able to gain more traffic will be able to enjoy lower costs and may be able to force the other out of the market. The existence and extent of scale economies at airports is disputed, though the presence of large indivisibilities, especially in the provision of runways, means that only large cities are likely to be able to have several runways and several airports. If natural monopoly is present, a profit-oriented airport will have an incentive to use its market power and increase prices. Alternatively, a non-profit-oriented airport might charge high prices and allow costs to rise. Governments might regulate airports to prevent this from occurring.
These explanations are not mutually exclusive. Whatever the explanation, few cities other than very large ones have more than one airport. This said, there may be secondary airports on a cityā€™s fringes that can compete, at least for some traffic, with the main airport. In addition, in the densely populated regions of countries such as the UK and Germany, there may be several airports that residents regard as equally accessible. Thus competition can exist, though often does not.
In this study, we find that competition between airports does exist in several regions. Thus, there is competition between the airports in the UK outside London, and this competition appears sufficiently strong to discipline their pricing. There are also many examples of monopoly airports where there is only one airport in a city and the nearest other airport is too far away to provide effective competition. In between, there are many situations where there is competition between airports for some traffic, for example between a fringe secondary airport and a major city airport for (LCC) traffic. Airports, though distant from one another, can compete in some markets, for example, for duty-free goods or as bases for LCCs. Major airports may be able to compete for hub traffic. Competition can also take place within airports, for example, between separately owned terminals.
The issue of competition between airports is of interest for several reasons:
ā€¢ If it is strong, it may be feasible to dispense with direct regulation of airports. Granted that regulation can be costly in efficiency terms, even imperfect competition may be preferable to imperfect regulation.
ā€¢ Even if competition is not strong enough to dispense with regulation, it may still provide a spur to improved performance.
ā€¢ When several airports are being privatized, governments must assess whether the benefits from selling them as a group to one owner outweigh any gains that might be achieved through selling them separately to facilitate competition.
ā€¢ With many airports now being privately owned, the issue arises of whether mergers or alliances between potentially competing airports should be permitted ā€“ the case of Schiphol and Paris Charles de Gaulle, which can compete as hubs, being a case in point.
We have organized the chapters under the following headings:
ā€¢ How do airports compete and how robust is competition between them? This section provides an overview of the state of competition and explores whether the current form of competition can increase efficiency and economic welfare. Airports seem to compete in various ways, but is there evidence of strong competition? In our view the evidence is not clear and it varies from country to country and region to region. Furthermore, the development of competition does not mean that the outcome is necessarily beneficial; more competition does not guarantee an improvement in economic welfare.
ā€¢ How do travellers choose an airport and how does this affect the competitive process? This is an essential aspect of competition. In some less densely populated countries, travellers have little choice as to which airport to use. In Europe, with a well-developed land transport infrastructure, this can be different; but time and travel costs play an important role. Similarly, long-haul connecting passengers have a choice of a number of airports they can use, which can result in airports which are a long distance apart being in the same market. Imagine a world in which travel and time to access airports were reduced to minimal levels ā€“ in such a world, all airports would become close substitutes. However, even with highspeed trains, time and travel costs remain important, and congested motorways add to the complexity of the traveller choice problem.
ā€¢ What is the evidence for competition in the airport industry? As the intensity of competition varies from country to country we have selected case studies from Greece, Germany and the UK.
ā€¢ What issues for airport and competition policy emerge? Here we deal with the issues identified earlier of market power, through joint ownership of potentially competing airports.

How Do Airports Compete and How Strong is Competition?

In Part A of the book empirical evidence on the nature of competition is presented. Morrell provides an overview of how airports compete in Europe. He notes that airports are intermodal hubs through which passengers are transferred from work or home to their final destinations, combining different transport modes. Airports compete with one another to attract airlines and he gives many examples for the different ways how, and against whom, they compete. Morrell emphasizes that airports offer airlines incentives and even subsidies to attract new routes or to base aircraft at their airport. The EU Commission views state aid as discriminatory if it is not open to all airlines. Morrell analyses several cases and highlights their importance (see chapters by Kristoferitsch and Elliott).
MĆ¼ller-Rostin et al. analyse a particular, though important, aspect of competition. In other industries, entry and exit are drivers of the competitive process and lead to welfare maximizing results in the long run. Compared to other industries, only a few airports have entered or exited the European airport sector. This suggests that the intensity of competition depends more on how the incumbents behave than on new entry.
There are two chapters that look at the issue of competition in relation to airlines. Pels and Verhoef argue that, without congestion, the ability by airports to abuse market power is limited if airlines are forced, through competition, to set fares equal to marginal cost. With congestion and with monopolistic behaviour of the airlines the airport can use its dominant position to raise charges above the competitive level.
Even large hubs are small firms compared to many airlines, which typically are part of an even larger airline alliance. Airports blamed for excessive market power claim that this fact has been overlooked. Instead of exploiting their users, they are facing substantial countervailing power from airlines. Button reviews this concept first developed by Kenneth Galbraith in 1952. While it was criticized by mainstream economists, he sees some relevance as it highlights outcomes which are either monopolistic or competitive. Applying it to the airport industry Button finds that countervailing power is hard to test. He analyses possible outcomes for traditional airlines and LCCs and for collective action of airlines, and discusses forms of price discrimination by airports as an indication of the strength of countervailing power.
Forsyth takes up the topic of Morrellā€™s chapter, namely increased competition between the major and the secondary airport combined with subsidies for secondary airports served by LCCs. He points out that the popular belief that ā€˜more competition leads to improved efficiencyā€™ might not be true for airports where subsidies are present. While not denying that competition can have positive effects, he doubts that this is necessarily the case in the airport industry with indivisibilities, significant sunk costs, imperfect regulation of major airports and subsidies available to some secondary airports.
Cost conditions are recognized as an important driver of the feasibility of competition. Pels et al. analyse how airport costs vary with size across a sample of airports from around the world, using a translog cost function. They conclude that short run average operational costs decrease with output, with passenger numbers being more closely associated with falling costs than air transport movements. However, when a quality variable is introduced, the elasticity of cost with respect to output is decreased in some specifications.
The chapters by Graham and by Kincaid and Tretheway analyse strategies of airports facing competition. Graham uses Porterā€™s ā€˜five forcesā€™ analysis to determine the threats and opportunities airports face. Regarding new entrants and substitutes, the threats are low compared with other industries. The forces of supply and consumer power, as well as internal rivalry, differ and cannot be generalized. Airports so far have been reluctant to adopt generic competitive strategies such as cost leadership and product differentiation, except for some niche markets such as LCCs and freight. Graham observes no head-to-head competition, but a growing demand for applying competitive strategies. Kincaid and Tretheway, on the other hand, tend to be more optimistic about the competitive nature of the industry than Graham. They emphasize the change of airports from passive service providers to active promoters of their business and region. Airports have developed marketing strategies and search on their own for new service opportunities, which they actively present to airlines to develop. They show how airports can define their product and price, and promote and distribute them. They provide examples of best practice, such as differentiating their product by developing specific features. These include passenger facilitation and baggage handling; pricing airlines differently at different stages of their business relationship; creating awareness of specific services and promoting their airport through websites; and good placement in computer reservation systems.
Tretheway and Andriulaitis describe the general evolution of the air cargo market and the trend towards a more competitive environment. Air cargo has been capturing an increasing proportion of trade, partly because of a growing proportion of high-value and often low-volume goods that are being transported The addition of new passenger gateways in major areas of economic activity has helped enormously in pushing up air cargo volumes. The development of secondary airports has provided additional, more cargo-friendly options.
By analysing the whole value chain the authors show how the bargaining power of the individual players have shifted and what the likely effect is on airports. They emphasize the growing influence of freight forwarders, the emergence of specialized air cargo freighters and the combination of air freight with trucking that led to the expansion of the geographic scope of an airportā€™s catchment area. This development has opened up new, and more competitive, options for shippers as numerous combinations of gateways/air service providers are now available to a wider range of shippers.

Traveller Choice and Airport Competition

Traveller and shipper choice lies at the heart of the airport competition issue ā€“ the strength of this competition depends on how good as substitutes travellers regard different airports to be. Hess reviews ā€˜Modelling Air Travel Choiceā€™ and how econometricians have studied this choice by passengers. He outlines first the nature of air travel choices, which involves also the choice of airport, and then looks at how well the models have captured the complexity. Hess is highly critical, as most discrete choice models have incorporated only a subset of the choices ā€“ something which might seriously bias the results. He suggests various ways to improve the quality of the models, including the quality of the data.
Hess and Polak compare the methods and results of three studies on the way passengers choose airports in the San Francisco Bay area, with three main airports, and in Greater London with five airports. In general these studies confirm that passengers have a strong preference for their local airport. Convenient and fast access is important and only LCCs with massive fare reductions can overcome the disadvantage of less accessible airports. Even travellers visiting friends and relatives are willing to pay a premium of $28 to fly from their closest airport. Furthermore, the way business travellers value frequent flier programmes is instructive for airport strategy. These travellers are willing to pay a premium of up to $125 for flights covered by such programmes and are therefore less willing to substitute airports.
An accessible treatment of the complexities of modelling the demand for air travel, and of airport choice models, is provided by Gaudry. He presents a detailed treatment of a critical feature of demand modelling practice that has important implications for airport competition and hub stability ā€“ specifically the ā€˜independence of irrelevant alternativesā€™ assumption which imposes strong substitution assumptions on the models. He notes that in the modelling effort the treatment of the fastest growing component of air passenger demand, non-business trips, is particularly challenging. To model these types of trips within the current modelling framework there must be clear reference to alternatives in mode and path or airline company choice representation procedures. This arises because passenger flows are interdependent and therefore the utility derivable from the alternatives cannot be defined only by reference to own transport conditions.
Gaudry also provides a comprehensive summary of how Standard Box-Cox endogenous form specifications contribute to a much improved representation of the role of transport characteristics and performance within the current demand modelling structures. He argues that in order to include the rapidly growing leisure passenger component into the models investigating competition among airports requires the use of spatial correlation processes in Generation-Distribution models, as well as the use of Generalized Box-Cox specifications. These newer modeling approaches should be used in both mode choice as well as route choice analysis. In both cases, the strong substitution assumptions of choice modeling are avoided. Specifically, the Independence of Irrelevant Alternatives (IIA) assumption is avoided in realistic ways.

Case Studies of Airport Competition

We have selected a few case studies to analyse in depth the nature and strength of airport competition in Germany, Greece and the UK.
Germany has one of densest airport networks in Europe, and also a comparatively well-developed, high-speed motorway system. Malina develops a measure for market power taking account also of intermodal competition. He shows that most of the small airports face competition, but that the large airports such as Berlin, Frankfurt, Hamburg, Munich and Stuttgart lack good substitutes. Competition could be enhanced if, for example, the airports in the metropolitan region of Berlin were operated independently.
Strobach analyses the catchment areas of airports in southern Germany with a view to developing an indicator of competitiveness between airports for residents of different zones in the region. He develops an index based on access (time and cost) to potentially competing airports, on airport quality (including flight frequency) and parking availability. He evaluates the index for nine airports in the broader region. This index indicates which airport is likely to prove most competitive in attracting passengers from a given zone.
Papatheodorou examines the extent of concentration of passengers using the airports of Greece. Airport passenger traffic tends to be regionally based, with traffic being closely related to regional population or gross domestic product (GDP). Greek airports have some scope to gain more traffic by competing for direct flights from the main origin airports. However, while some airports could prove competitive, it is likely that they would need to make considerable financial commitments to develop their facilities.
In contrast to the more sceptical views on the strength of competition in continental Europe, Starkie argues that the UK airport industry is a competitive one; but even small airports are at least breaking even, and high fixed costs are not an obstacle for entry. This is largely due to the fact that there is an abundance of former military airfields which can be turned into airports and which, like the example of Doncaster airport, show that new or small airports can challenge incumbent airports such as Manchester effectively. As most airports are only about an hourā€™s driving distance apart, the hinterland of airports overlap. Airports can be good substitutes, especially if they cannot price discriminate among passengers. Starkie challenges the view that takes for granted that airports are natural monopolies which automatically have to be regulated. Regulation might be necessary for some airports, but airport policy should adopt the view that ā€˜a competitive framework is an achievable objective for a national airport poli...

Table of contents

  1. Cover Page
  2. Half Title Page
  3. Title Page
  4. Copyright Page
  5. Contents
  6. List of Figures
  7. List of Tables
  8. Acknowledgements
  9. Editors and Contributors
  10. 1 Introduction and Overview
  11. Part A How Do Airports Compete and How Strong is Competition?
  12. Part B Traveller Choice and Airport Competition
  13. Part C Case Studies of Airport Competition
  14. Part D Policy Issues
  15. Airport Competition: Some Key References
  16. Airport Index
  17. Index