The History of Bankruptcy
eBook - ePub

The History of Bankruptcy

  1. 252 pages
  2. English
  3. ePUB (mobile friendly)
  4. Available on iOS & Android
eBook - ePub

The History of Bankruptcy

Book details
Book preview
Table of contents
Citations

About This Book

This volume takes up bankruptcy in early modern Europe, when its frequency made it not only an economic problem but a personal tragedy and a social evil. Using legal, business and personal records, the essays in this volume examine the impact of failure on business organizations and practices, capital formation and circulation, economic institutions and ethics, and human networks and relations in the so-called "transition" to modern society, from the early-sixteenth to the early-nineteenth century. One group of essays concentrates on the German-speaking world and shows a common concern for the microeconomics of bankruptcy, that is, for such issues as the structure of the firm, the nature of its capital, and the practices of its partners, especially their assessment of risk. Another group of essays shifts the focus from Central to Western and Northern Europe and away from the microeconomics of the early modern firm to an institutional consideration of bankruptcy. The final group of essays turns to Southern Europe, especially the Mediterranean basin, to assess bankruptcy not as an unfortunate result of crisis, but as an intentional response to crisis. All of the contributions are the result of original research; many of the scholars publish in English for the first time.

All of the chapters are founded on close archival research, offering insights not only into business organization and practice but also into social and cultural aspects of economic life from the late sixteenth to the early nineteenth century.

Frequently asked questions

Simply head over to the account section in settings and click on “Cancel Subscription” - it’s as simple as that. After you cancel, your membership will stay active for the remainder of the time you’ve paid for. Learn more here.
At the moment all of our mobile-responsive ePub books are available to download via the app. Most of our PDFs are also available to download and we're working on making the final remaining ones downloadable now. Learn more here.
Both plans give you full access to the library and all of Perlego’s features. The only differences are the price and subscription period: With the annual plan you’ll save around 30% compared to 12 months on the monthly plan.
We are an online textbook subscription service, where you can get access to an entire online library for less than the price of a single book per month. With over 1 million books across 1000+ topics, we’ve got you covered! Learn more here.
Look out for the read-aloud symbol on your next book to see if you can listen to it. The read-aloud tool reads text aloud for you, highlighting the text as it is being read. You can pause it, speed it up and slow it down. Learn more here.
Yes, you can access The History of Bankruptcy by Thomas Max Safley in PDF and/or ePUB format, as well as other popular books in Volkswirtschaftslehre & Banken & Bankwesen. We have over one million books available in our catalogue for you to explore.

Information

Publisher
Routledge
Year
2013
ISBN
9781135076597

1 Introduction

A history of bankruptcy and bankruptcy in history
Thomas Max Safley
Insolvency and bankruptcy are persistent realities of economic life that have long provoked comment and criticism. As early as the sixteenth century, an Augsburg chronicler remarked about one of the most notorious bankrupts of his day that:
he often oppressed the common good and the poor man with his commercial activity, not only with large, reputable wares, but also with smaller, poorer goods. He bought up ash wood in good times, and brought it to market at better times, the same with wine, and lute strings, and often bought the entire supply of a good at a higher price than it was worth in order to put pressure on his competitors, who could not afford to buy it, after which he would raise the price of the good in all lands and sell as he pleased. No merchant worth 50,000 or 100,000 gulden could trade in comparison with him, because he profited wherever he wished.1
Here was profit-seeking in every saleable good, speculation in commodity futures, competition on price-point, manipulation of foreign markets and an utter disregard for every non-advantageous consideration. The account detailed how complex credit transactions combined with opportunistic business partners led to a bankruptcy that resulted in extended litigation and ended with the ruin of his family and hundreds of his creditors. That he died in chains—the last detail of the account—was little more than justice. This chronicler and others after him2 immortalize the greed, and question why the bankrupt lost sight of the early modern merchant-financier's maxim, servare modum finemque tenere, Lucan's attribution to Cato, urging moderation in pursuit of reasonable goals, which serves today as the motto of the House of Rothschild. Apart from Villani's report of the fourteenth-century collapse of the great trading companies of the Bardi and Peruzzi,3 it is one of the earliest existing accounts of an actual bankruptcy.
Some 200 years later, an anonymous moralist of the eighteenth century decried bankruptcy and bankrupts in general:
They steal under the appearance of an honorable man. They cut a figure with other people's money. They win friends with unrighteous Mammon. They are the best of men, because they give everything to their wives. When they are unable to carry on, they give up their good names as well as their businesses. They pay no one. It is said, they were unfortunate. They lose everything and live afterward from the wealth of their wives as comfortably as before.4
His text points at many of the same issues: profit and greed, credit and debt, non-payment and deception, reputation and punishment. Yet, there is no assumption of a good man gone astray. There is no just ending.
His tone suggests that something has changed. What had emerged in the sixteenth century as an economic and social problem had become a sign of economic decline and moral decay, an index of social and personal failure. Bankruptcy had moved from being something extraordinary, like the sighting of a comet or the birth of a two-headed calf, to being something systemic. Capitalistic practices no longer needed to be described; they could be assumed. Bankrupts all deserved the rope, a prescription not necessarily original in itself,5 because the damage they caused was not limited to a group of reckless high-flyers. Merchants and bankers relied on other people's capital. When they misrepresented the investment risks or mismanaged financial affairs, they robbed others of their fortunes, their homes, their jobs and their futures. They were often the least affected by the consequences of their deeds. Recent events echo these sentiments, even as the prescriptive measures against bankruptcy have lost most of their draconian bite.
This volume attempts to address the transition framed by the two commentators. Its contributors take up bankruptcy in early modern Europe from a wide variety of perspectives. At the heart of their inquiries lie questions about the identity and fate of bankrupts, the generation and redistribution of wealth, the organization and reorganization of enterprise and the emergence and transformation of institutions over time. Together they make clear that what has become generally known as “commercial capitalism,” by no means new in the sixteenth century, was practiced in new forms, underwritten by new institutions and associated with new meanings in the eighteenth.
Bankruptcy belongs to the essence of capitalism. Though failure, conceived in its broadest terms, can occur under any kind of economic system, the particularities of bankruptcy suggest a close identification with one particular kind. While no precise definition of capitalism finds universal approval, scholars agree generally that it involves private ownership of the means of production, creation of goods and services for profit in a market and, to a varying degree, governmental support for private property in the form of appropriate legal institutions. These characteristics—private property, market activity, legal institutions—appear readily in the reports and reflections of chronicler and moralist.
They inform the very definition of the term. The root, bankrupt, appears in English in the sixteenth century, as a term borrowed from the French (banqueroute) and Italian (banca rotta) to identify “the wreck or break-up of a trader's business in consequence of his failure to pay his creditors; or the shutting up or desertion of his place of business without paying his liabilities.”6 The Italian banca rotta referred transparently to the destruction of a merchant's trading table, or bank, usually located in the marketplace among those of other merchants, when he failed to pay his debts. Bankrupt was commonly taken to mean:
a merchant, trader or other person, whose property and effects, on his becoming insolvent, are administered and distributed for the benefit of all his creditors, under that system of statutory regulations called the Bankrupt or Bankruptcy Laws. As these laws (which began in England with Acts 34 and 35 Henry VIII, c. 4) were originally directed against fraudulent traders, who absconded with the property of their creditors, or eluded the attempts of creditors to get at them.
The earlier senses were: in law, “a trader who secretes himself, or does certain other acts tending to defraud his creditors” (Blackstone); popularly, “one who has brought himself into debt by reckless expenditure or riotous living; a fugitive from his creditors, a broken man in sanctuary or outlawry.”7
Bankruptcy carried an enduring implication of dishonesty and profligacy, because the malversation of private property made it offensive. In legal parlance and in common usage today, bankruptcy has been largely stripped of moral censure and has come to refer strictly to the legal process that begins with a declaration—either by bankrupt or creditors—of a person's inability to pay his or her debts. It is “The state of a person who has been adjudged by a court to be insolvent. The court orders the compulsory administration of the bankrupt's affairs so that his assets can be fairly distributed among his creditors.”8 It distinguishes itself thus from insolvency, that is, the unofficial financial situation from which bankruptcy results, and default on any single debt or obligation. The involvement of a court of law provides a forum and—significantly, for the historian—produces a record, in which the related questions of the financial state of the bankrupt, his actions and intentions and the causes and consequences of his bankruptcy are examined, disputed and, occasionally, resolved. These definitions confirm again and again the systematic existence of private property invested for productive purposes in the market and protected by an array of legal institutions. Their change over time indicates that the social and legal responses to bankruptcy became more sophisticated.
That the term came into much more frequent, colorful and varied usage in the sixteenth century is not mere happenstance. It seems likely that bankruptcy became more frequent from the late fifteenth century. Whether this was indeed the case and why it might have been so remain matters of conjecture. It is hard to ignore the numbers of bankruptcies that begin to mount in the sixteenth century.
Take as a single example the German imperial city of Augsburg. As early as 1560, the local chronicler Paul Hektor Mair counted no fewer than 26 merchants who “became bankrupt and, because of debts, sought sanctuary, fled the city, or suffered arrest until they settled and were released.”9 Had he been able to extend his count to 1580, as Jakob Strieder did in 1938, the total would have risen to 70 “great and famous commercial houses.”10 More recent surveys have set at 63 the number of bankruptcies in Augsburg between 1529 and 1580.11 If one extends the period of study to 1800, the number may rise as high as 250, and this reflects only those cases that came to the attention of the authorities. Similar numbers may be developed for other, early modern, commercial centers.
The causes were manifold. The inconsistencies of state finance certainly played a part in many bankruptcies. The ambitions of princes and the costs of their policies rose rapidly from the fifteenth century, and merchants with disposable capital were willing to provide credit, accepting the real risk of non-payment for a high rate of interest. The results were both spectacular returns and equally spectacular ruptures.12 The Spanish suspension of payments, followed by the Dutch, French and Portuguese, all of which occurred in the sixteenth century, swept away those merchant bankers not so far-sighted as to have diversified their engagements.13 Commercial developments finished the rest. European silver mining, the great source of capital for overseas exploration and Renaissance culture, suffered a steady decline in productivity and profitability after the mid-sixteenth century. A rising tide of minerals, particularly silver, and other commodities from the Americas and Asia speeded the fall. The consequences of a so-called “rise of the Atlantic economies”14 have been debated among scholars,15 but they generally agree that the European economy as a whole experienced inflationary expansion, with different localities or regions profiting at different points in time. A growing, global economy, based ever more intensely on imported and exported commodities, created competitive challenges and disadvantages to which many merchants were not equal.
The resulting bankruptcies have created the impression of a turning-point in economic history. Until very recently, those of the sixteenth century marked the end of “The Age of the Fugger,” “The Catastrophe of the Early Capitalist Age,” or “The Collapse of Southern- and Middle-European Early Capitalism.”16 Though close studies of the economies of Europe at that time reveal few unequivocal indicators of crisis,17 they continue to associate this wave of failures with capitalistic practices in a society and economy that seem deserving of the term. Joseph Schumpeter, whose work in many ways defines the modern discussion of failure and capitalism argued that there was no separating the two, that the one was intrinsic to the other. He wrote:
A society is called capitalist if it entrusts its economic process to the guidance of the private businessman. This may be said to imply, first, private ownership of nonpersonal means of production … second, production for private account, i.e., production by private initiative for private profit.18
He thus calls attention to the individual entrepreneur as the agent, to private enterprise as the modality and to personal profit as the motive of change under capitalism. As he explains in Business Cycles, entrepreneurs are “New Men,” whose enterprises are “New Firms” that pursue “innovation” by creating new commodities, forming new organizations or opening new markets.19 Even as it drives capitalism forward, innovation provokes resistance, because it threatens the status quo.20 This is the essence of “creative destruction,” as he defines it in Capitalism, Socialism and Democracy, which “incessantly revolutionizes the economic structure from within, incessantly destroying the old one, incessantly creating a new one.”21 For Schumpeter, well aware that capitalism wreaks havoc on social relations and undermines moral values, the benefits of increased prosperity outweigh the costs in human suffering.
A close study of failure suggests a more ambivalent view. The chapters that follow take up bankruptcy, insolvency and default to explore various aspects of economic life in the early modern period. They examine the identities of and relationships among debtors and creditors. They reconstruct the organizations and workings of their businesses. They t...

Table of contents

  1. Cover
  2. Half Title
  3. Routledge explorations in economic history
  4. Full Title
  5. Copyright
  6. Contents
  7. List of Contributors
  8. 1 Introduction: a history of bankruptcy and bankruptcy in history
  9. PART I Social contexts
  10. PART II Business practices
  11. PART III Institutional developments
  12. Bibliography
  13. Index