Running the World's Markets
eBook - ePub

Running the World's Markets

The Governance of Financial Infrastructure

  1. 472 pages
  2. English
  3. ePUB (mobile friendly)
  4. Available on iOS & Android
eBook - ePub

Running the World's Markets

The Governance of Financial Infrastructure

Book details
Book preview
Table of contents
Citations

About This Book

The efficiency, safety, and soundness of financial markets depend on the operation of core infrastructure--exchanges, central counter-parties, and central securities depositories. How these institutions are governed critically affects their performance. Yet, despite their importance, there is little certainty, still less a global consensus, about their governance. Running the World's Markets examines how markets are, and should be, run.
Utilizing a wide variety of arguments and examples from throughout the world, Ruben Lee identifies and evaluates the similarities and differences between exchanges, central counter-parties, and central securities depositories. Drawing on knowledge and experience from various disciplines, including business, economics, finance, law, politics, and regulation, Lee employs a range of methodologies to tackle different goals. Conceptual analysis is used to examine theoretical issues, survey evidence to describe key aspects of how market infrastructure institutions are governed and regulated globally, and case studies to detail the particular situations and decisions at specific institutions. The combination of these approaches provides a unique and rich foundation for evaluating the complex issues raised.
Lee analyzes efficient forms of governance, how regulatory powers should be allocated, and whether regulatory intervention in governance is desirable. He presents guidelines for identifying the optimal governance model for any market infrastructure institution within the context of its specific environment. Running the World's Markets provides a definitive and peerless reference for how to govern and regulate financial markets.

Frequently asked questions

Simply head over to the account section in settings and click on “Cancel Subscription” - it’s as simple as that. After you cancel, your membership will stay active for the remainder of the time you’ve paid for. Learn more here.
At the moment all of our mobile-responsive ePub books are available to download via the app. Most of our PDFs are also available to download and we're working on making the final remaining ones downloadable now. Learn more here.
Both plans give you full access to the library and all of Perlego’s features. The only differences are the price and subscription period: With the annual plan you’ll save around 30% compared to 12 months on the monthly plan.
We are an online textbook subscription service, where you can get access to an entire online library for less than the price of a single book per month. With over 1 million books across 1000+ topics, we’ve got you covered! Learn more here.
Look out for the read-aloud symbol on your next book to see if you can listen to it. The read-aloud tool reads text aloud for you, highlighting the text as it is being read. You can pause it, speed it up and slow it down. Learn more here.
Yes, you can access Running the World's Markets by Ruben Lee,Ruben Lee in PDF and/or ePUB format, as well as other popular books in Economics & Monetary Policy. We have over one million books available in our catalogue for you to explore.

Information

Year
2010
ISBN
9781400836970

PART ONE

Background Information and Analyses

CHAPTER ONE

Definitions

TO MANY PEOPLE it is clear what are the “infrastructure institutions” in financial markets. They are the exchanges, CCPs, and CSDs that provide the trading, clearing, settlement, and sometimes other, core functions for cash and derivative markets.1 These institutions are indeed the focus of attention here. There are, however, also many reasons why the definitions of an infrastructure, an exchange, a CCP, and a CSD are all quite opaque. This is important, as the identification of a particular organization as one of these types of institutions can have significant commercial, regulatory, and policy consequences. This chapter aims to provide some basic insights into the definitions and nature of an infrastructure, an exchange, a CCP, and a CSD; and to explore the reasons why these concepts are sometimes ambiguous and controversial. A comprehensive examination of each of these different concepts would require a series of complex and broad analyses, and is not undertaken here.2
The chapter is composed of three sections. In the first, the meaning and nature of what is an infrastructure is explored. Some comments on the definitions and nature of exchanges, CCPs, and CSDs, and on the functions they deliver, are provided in the second section. Brief conclusions are offered in the last section.

INFRASTRUCTURE

Understanding how the term “infrastructure” has generally been employed and the key factors relevant for determining whether an institution is an infrastructure illuminates how the term may be used regarding institutions in financial markets, and the implications of doing so.
Meaning and Use of the Term
An examination of a broad range of definitions and uses of the term “infrastructure” highlights eight key nonexclusive factors and attributes that contribute towards identifying an institution as an infrastructure:
1. An infrastructure may be, or provide, the basic equipment, facility, foundation, framework, installation, system, or services that support or underly some form of structure, system, or activity, defined quite broadly. Such a structure, system, or activity may include a corporation, an organization, a productive process, a community, a city, an economy, a society, a nation, or a group of nations.3 The goods or services provided by an infrastructure are often both consumed directly and also used as inputs for a wide range of goods or services produced by users of the infrastructure institution. In this context, an infrastructure is often referred to as a “utility”—although this term, itself, is not easy to define.4
2. An infrastructure may be critical, essential, or necessary, to support commerce, economic activity and development, or whatever other activities are facilitated by the system it operates.5 Given the critical nature of the basic goods or services that an infrastructure provides, there are frequently concerns about access to these goods or services.6
3. An infrastructure may be, or provide, a network.7 In the economic sphere, such a network typically facilitates the delivery of goods and services, or links together the participants in a market, and is thus part of the structure underlying a market. The relationship between relevant producers and consumers takes place on, or via, the shared facilities or single medium provided by the infrastructure. A network is typically composed of both the physical structure linking market participants, and the associated commercial arrangements and rules for using this structure.
4. An infrastructure may exhibit economies of scale.8
5. An infrastructure may require large, long-term, immobile, and sunk investments.9
6. An infrastructure may be, or operate, a natural monopoly.10
7. An infrastructure may provide beneficial public goods or services, in addition to the specific goods and services it delivers directly.11 There are two key attributes of a pure public good or service: it is nonrivalrous, so that its consumption by one person does not prevent other people from consuming it; and it is nonexcludable, so that it is not possible to stop somebody from consuming it. An often-cited example of a public good is good health, as facilitated by water and sanitation infrastructures.
8. An infrastructure may have some form of government or public sector involvement, defined very broadly.12 For this reason, the term “public works” is sometimes used interchangeably for the term “infrastructure.” The role of government or public sector involvement in infrastructures has been quite diverse. As Waller and Frischmann (2007, 12) note:
The government has played and continues to play a significant and widely-accepted role in ensuring the provision of many infrastructure resources. While private parties and markets play an increasingly important role in providing many types of traditional infrastructure due to a wave of privatization as well as cooperative ventures between industry and government, the government’s position as provider, coordinator, subsidizer, and/or regulator of traditional infrastructure provision remains intact in most communities throughout the world.
Several implications and aspects of this list of factors and attributes that contribute towards identifying an institution as being an infrastructure are noteworthy:
1. There are close links between many of them. For example, the presence of economies of scale is often associated both with a natural monopoly and with a network industry.
2. The presence of any one of the identified factors and attributes is not sufficient to determine that an institution is an infrastructure.
3. None of them are exclusive to infrastructure institutions.
4. The term “infrastructure” has been used in different contexts for different reasons. Unsurprisingly, therefore, different meanings have been assigned to the term.
5. A central aspect of an infrastructure is its importance, however this quality is defined. This importance may arise, in legal terms, because it is, or runs, an essential facility; in economic terms, because it is a monopoly; or its importance may lie in other directions, affecting social, political, or other factors.
6. The classification of an institution as an infrastructure, or not, may change. For example, technological changes and market developments may mean that an institution that was historically thought to be, and defined as, an infrastructure, given its importance, may no longer be so considered, if it becomes subject to competition.
7. It may be difficult to define an institution as an infrastructure if it undertakes multiple functions. In particular, if a single institution undertakes some functions that are recognized as infrastructure functions, and some others that are not, perhaps because they are provided in competitive markets, then it may be unclear how to characterize the institution. Should it be classified as an infrastructure institution, even though some of its functions are typically provided by non-infrastructure institutions? Or is it more useful to define activities as being associated with infrastructure provision rather than institutions?
8. The presence of these factors and attributes may have important policy implications.
A range of assets, services, organizations, and industries have typically been identified as infrastructure.13 They include the basic physical systems of a nation, particularly its transport (airports, air traffic control, bridges, buses, rail, roads, ports, and public transit), communications (post, telephone, and sometimes the Internet), energy (electricity and gas supply and distribution facilities, and sometimes oil), and water and sanitation systems. In addition, infrastructure may include public and social facilities, such as police, fire, and emergency services, schools, hospitals, recreation facilities, prisons, and government systems, such as courts, ministries, and parliaments.
In financial markets, the term “infrastructure” has been widely used to refer to exchanges, CCPs, and CSDs as providers of trading, clearing, and settlement services,14 and also to payment systems.15 It has also infrequently been used to refer to other providers of trading, clearing, and settlement services.
A range of examples illustrate how the term has been used. The UK’s Financial Services Authority (FSA) defined “infrastructure providers” to be
entities whose business is organising and supporting the functioning of markets. Infrastructure providers include exchanges, non-exchange (or “alternative”) trading systems, clearing houses and market service providers generally.16
More informally, Oleg Vyugin, a Russian regulator from the Federal Service for Financial Markets, noted that “double the infrastructure is madness,” when discussing why Russia’s two major exchanges should consider merging to improve their competitiveness against overseas exchanges.17
The Committee on Payment and Settlement Systems (CPSS) of the Bank for International Settlements (BIS) and the Technical Committee of IOSCO have jointly developed recommendations for Securities Settlement Systems (SSS), the first sentence of which notes that such entities “are a critical component of the infrastructure of global financial markets.”18 The committees have also developed recommendations for CCPs, and in doing so noted,
Although a CCP has the potential to reduce risks to market participants significantly, it also concentrates risks and responsibilities for risk management. Therefore, the effectiveness of a CCP’s risk control and the adequacy of its financial resources are critical aspects of the infrastructure of the markets it serves.19
Similarly, a paper prepared for the International Monetary Fund (IMF) noted that
the smooth functioning of and confidence in the securities market depend on the efficiency and reliability of its infrastructure. In particular, it is crucial that the transfer of ownership from the seller to the buyer in exchange for payment takes place in a safe and efficient manner.20
The European Centrol Bank (ECB) has established a Contact Group on Euro Securities Infrastructures, which “addresses issues and developments which are relevant for the euro securities settlement industry and which are of common interest for the Eurosystem, market infrastructures and market participants.”21
When describing clearing and settlement as the infrastructure underpinning financial markets, one metaphor that is very commonly used is that of plumbing.22 The European Commission, for example, used this metaphor in explaining that such institutions are “vital, but unglamorous and forgotten until something goes wrong.”23 A report from the European Parliament used the same metaphor, similarly noting that clearing and settlement is “largely invisible, seldom understood and frequently overlooked but causes really unpleasant problems for everyone if it goes wrong.”24 As well as equating clearing and settlement systems with sanitation systems, which are typically themselves accepted as infrastructure, the metaphor also implies that clearing and settlement systems provide a public good in preventing things from “going wrong.”
Key Attributes of an Infrastructure Institution
Five of the key factors relevant for determining whether an institution is an “infrastructure” are briefly examined here.
ESSENTIAL FACILITY DOCTRINE
A commonly accepted attribute of infrastructure institutions is that the goods or services they produce are essential in some manner. This characteristic has in some contexts brought them within the purview of a legal doctrine, initially developed under US antitrust law, called the “essential facility” doctrine.25 The key thrust of the doctrine is that a monopolistic operator of an essential facility may be obliged to provide access to it to a competitor. In the past, four main criteria have needed to be satisfied under US law for such a possibility to arise:26 (1) the monopolist must control access to an essential facility, (2) the facility cannot practically or reasonably be duplicated by the competitor, (3) the monopolist must deny access to the competitor, and (4) it is feasible for the monopolist to grant access to the competitor.
The essential facility doctrine has been applied by US courts to secure the access of competitors to various institutions that could be considered infrastructures, including a terminal railroad,27 an information network for the press,28 an electricity network,29 a telecommunications network,30 and ski facilities.31
As discussed by Waller and Frischmann (2006), however, the continued applicability of the essential facility doctrine has come into question and been subject to criticism from a range of different sources. In 2004 the US Supreme Court expressed a strong reservation as to the pertinence of the doctrine due to its drawbacks on competition policy, noting,
Compelling such firms [i.e., with an essential facility] to share their advantage is in some tension with the underlying principles of antitrust law, sin...

Table of contents

  1. Cover
  2. Halftitle
  3. Title
  4. Copyright
  5. Dedication
  6. Contents
  7. Foreword and Acknowledgments
  8. List of Acronyms
  9. Introduction
  10. Part One: Background Information and Analysis
  11. Part Two: Survey Evidence
  12. Part Three: Case Studies
  13. Part Four: Policy Analysis and Recommendations
  14. Authorities
  15. Cases and Decisions
  16. Notes
  17. References
  18. List of Contributors
  19. Index