The Handbook of Organizational Economics
eBook - ePub

The Handbook of Organizational Economics

  1. 1,248 pages
  2. English
  3. ePUB (mobile friendly)
  4. Available on iOS & Android
eBook - ePub
Book details
Book preview
Table of contents
Citations

About This Book

The definitive introduction to organizational economics, with contributions by leaders in the field In even the most market-oriented economies, most economic transactions occur not in markets but inside managed organizations, particularly business firms. Organizational economics seeks to understand the nature and workings of such organizations and their impact on economic performance. This landmark book assembles the leading figures in organizational economics to present the first comprehensive view of both the current state of research in this fast-emerging field and where it might be headed. The Handbook of Organizational Economics surveys the major theories, evidence, and methods used in the field. It displays the breadth of topics in organizational economics, including the roles of individuals and groups in organizations, organizational structures and processes, the boundaries of the firm, contracts between and within firms, and more.The defining book on the subject, The Handbook of Organizational Economics is essential reading for researchers and students looking to understand this emerging field in economics.

  • Presents the first comprehensive treatment of organizational economics
  • Features contributions by leaders in the field
  • Unifies and extends existing literatures
  • Describes theoretical and empirical methods used today

Frequently asked questions

Simply head over to the account section in settings and click on “Cancel Subscription” - it’s as simple as that. After you cancel, your membership will stay active for the remainder of the time you’ve paid for. Learn more here.
At the moment all of our mobile-responsive ePub books are available to download via the app. Most of our PDFs are also available to download and we're working on making the final remaining ones downloadable now. Learn more here.
Both plans give you full access to the library and all of Perlego’s features. The only differences are the price and subscription period: With the annual plan you’ll save around 30% compared to 12 months on the monthly plan.
We are an online textbook subscription service, where you can get access to an entire online library for less than the price of a single book per month. With over 1 million books across 1000+ topics, we’ve got you covered! Learn more here.
Look out for the read-aloud symbol on your next book to see if you can listen to it. The read-aloud tool reads text aloud for you, highlighting the text as it is being read. You can pause it, speed it up and slow it down. Learn more here.
Yes, you can access The Handbook of Organizational Economics by Robert Gibbons, John Roberts, Robert Gibbons,John Roberts, Robert Gibbons, John Roberts in PDF and/or ePUB format, as well as other popular books in Business & Organisational Development. We have over one million books available in our catalogue for you to explore.

Information

Year
2012
ISBN
9781400845354

PART I

Foundations

1

Complementarity in Organizations

Erik Brynjolfsson and Paul Milgrom

1. Introduction

According to the American Heritage dictionary, a synergy is “the interaction of two or more agents or forces so that their combined effect is greater than the sum of their individual effects” or “cooperative interaction among groups, especially among the acquired subsidiaries or merged parts of a corporation, that creates an enhanced combined effect.” Complementarity, as we use the term, is a near synonym for “synergy,” but it is set in a decisionmaking context and defined in Section 1.2 with mathematical precision.
Complementarity is an important concept in organizational analysis, because it offers an approach to explaining patterns of organizational practices, how they fit with particular business strategies, and why different organizations choose different patterns and strategies. The formal analysis of complementarity is based on studying the interactions among pairs of interrelated decisions. For example, consider a company that is evaluating a triple of decisions: (i) whether to adopt a strategy that requires implementing frequent changes in its technology, (ii) whether to invest in a flexibly trained workforce, and (iii) whether to give workers more discretion in the organization of their work. Suppose that more-flexibly trained workers can make better use of discretion and that more-flexibly trained and autonomous workers make it easier to implement new technologies effectively, because workers are more likely to know what to do and how to solve problems. Then, there is a complementarity between several pairs of decisions, which is characteristic of a system of complements. The theory of complementarities predicts that these practices will tend to cluster. An organization with one of the practices is more likely to have the others as well. Suppose an organization employs these three practices. Should this organization now adopt job protections, incentive pay, or both? The answer depends in part on the presence or absence of complementarities: if these new practices enhance worker cooperation with management in periods of technical change, then they, too, should be part of the same system.
Table 1. Interactions in a system of complements
images
Often there is a related environmental variable that drives an entire system. In our example, suppose the organization operates in an environment that contains frequent, substantial opportunities to upgrade technology to save costs or improve products. Then it would be natural for the organization to favor the first practice—making frequent technical changes. Because of complementarities, this would in turn favor adopting the whole group of practices described above. The clustering of practices, the way choices depend on the environment, and the influence of each practice on the profitability of the others are all empirical propositions that we summarize with our example in Table 1.
Table 1 is a prototype for portraying and discussing the interactions in a system of complements. Each decision about a particular practice is labeled and appears in both a row and a column. We put the environmental variables in the rows below the double rule. In this case, there is just one: the frequency of valuable opportunities to upgrade technologies. To verify the system of complements, it suffices to check just the upper half of the table, because the complementarity relation is symmetric. Also, we can omit checking the diagonal entries, because complementarity is defined in terms of interactions among different decisions. The plus symbols in cells (1, 2) and (1, 3) of the table represent the complementarities that we have hypothesized as present between frequent technical changes and two other labor practices, while the plus in cell (2, 3) represents our hypothesis that flexibly trained workers use discretion more effectively than other workers do. Worker protection aligns workers’ long-term interests more closely with the firm’s interest, reducing resistance to change and enlisting workers in implementation. That accounts for the plus symbols in cells (1, 4) and (3, 4).
The plus in the last row indicates that the environmental variable directly favors one of the choices and, through the system of complements, indirectly favors all the others. We leave the cells blank when a priori we do not believe there to be a direct interaction. A version of this tool, called the “Matrix of Change,” has been used by managers and MBA students to analyze complementarities and thereby assess the feasibility, pace, scope, and location of organizational change efforts (Brynjolfsson et al. 1997).
1.1. Some Applications and Implications
Complementarity ideas can be usefully combined with ideas about the limits to coordination among separate firms to explore the scope of the firm. For example, in the early twentieth century, General Electric (GE) produced a wide array of products based on electric motors. Its intensive research into designing and producing electric motors complemented its strategy of producing a broad range of products using those motors. Improvements in the costs or capabilities of electric motors for one product line increased the probability of improvements for other product lines. Coordinating such variety in a single firm was favored by the concurrent development of a multidivisional organizational architecture.1
In addition, the analysis of complementarities can provide insights into organizational dynamics. For example, even when senior executives have a clear vision of a new strategy for a company, managing the change can be difficult or impossible (e.g., Argyris 1982; Siggelkow 2002b; Schein 2004).
Why is organizational change so difficult? Complementarities can provide part of the answer (Milgrom and Roberts 1990, 1992, 1995; Brynjolfsson et al. 1997). When many complementarities among practices exist in an established system, but practices from the established system and those from the new one conflict, then it is likely that the transition will be difficult, especially when decisions are decentralized. Because of the complementarities, changing only one practice, or a small set of them, is likely to reduce overall performance.2 The natural conclusion is that the organization should change all the practices in the new system simultaneously. However, making these changes all at once can be difficult or infeasible for at least three reasons.
First, there is a basic coordination problem. Actors who control different business practices, assets, markets, and strategies, including some that may be outside the direct control of the firm, need to coordinate on the scope, time, and content of the change. Furthermore, because the exact outcomes and optimal levels of each factor are likely to be at least partially unpredictable, these actors need to continue to agree to and coordinate on any additional adjustments and rent reallocations. All this effort requires accurate communication and an alignment of incentives.
Second, organizations inevitably consist not only of numerous explicit well-defined practices and choices but also many that are implicit or poor...

Table of contents

  1. Cover
  2. Half title
  3. Title
  4. Copyright
  5. Contents
  6. Contributors
  7. Introduction
  8. Part I Foundations
  9. Part II Methods
  10. Part III Within Firms: Individuals and Groups
  11. Part IV Within Firms: Structures and Processes
  12. Part V Between Firms
  13. Part VI Beyond Firms
  14. Name Index
  15. Subject Index