The Economists' Voice 2.0
eBook - ePub

The Economists' Voice 2.0

The Financial Crisis, Health Care Reform, and More

  1. English
  2. ePUB (mobile friendly)
  3. Available on iOS & Android
eBook - ePub

The Economists' Voice 2.0

The Financial Crisis, Health Care Reform, and More

Book details
Book preview
Table of contents
Citations

About This Book

The Economists' Voice: Top Economists Take On Today's Problems featured a core collection of accessible, timely essays on the challenges facing today's global markets and financial institutions. The Economists' Voice 2.0: The Financial Crisis, Health Care Reform, and More is the next installment in this popular series, gathering together the strongest essays published in The Economist's Voice, a nonpartisan online journal, so that students and general readers can gain a deeper understanding of the financial developments shaping their world.

This collection contains thirty-two essays written by academics, economists, presidential advisors, legal specialists, researchers, consultants, and policy makers. They tackle the plain economics and architecture of health care reform, its implications for society and the future of the health insurance industry, and the value of the health insurance subsidies and exchanges built into the law. They consider the effects of financial regulatory reform, the possibilities for ratings reform, and the issue of limiting bankers' pay. An objective examination of the financial crisis and bank bailouts results in two indispensable essays on investment banking regulation after Bear Stearns and the positives and negatives of the Paulson/Bernanke bailout. Contributors weigh the merits of future rescues and suggest alternative strategies for addressing the next financial crisis. A final section examines a unique array of topics: the stability of pension security bonds; the value of a carbon tax, especially in fostering economic and environmental sustainability; the counterintuitive perils of net neutrality; the unforeseen consequences of government debt; the meaning of the Google book search settlement; and the unexploited possibilities for profit in NFL overtime games.

Frequently asked questions

Simply head over to the account section in settings and click on ā€œCancel Subscriptionā€ - itā€™s as simple as that. After you cancel, your membership will stay active for the remainder of the time youā€™ve paid for. Learn more here.
At the moment all of our mobile-responsive ePub books are available to download via the app. Most of our PDFs are also available to download and we're working on making the final remaining ones downloadable now. Learn more here.
Both plans give you full access to the library and all of Perlegoā€™s features. The only differences are the price and subscription period: With the annual plan youā€™ll save around 30% compared to 12 months on the monthly plan.
We are an online textbook subscription service, where you can get access to an entire online library for less than the price of a single book per month. With over 1 million books across 1000+ topics, weā€™ve got you covered! Learn more here.
Look out for the read-aloud symbol on your next book to see if you can listen to it. The read-aloud tool reads text aloud for you, highlighting the text as it is being read. You can pause it, speed it up and slow it down. Learn more here.
Yes, you can access The Economists' Voice 2.0 by Aaron Edlin, Joseph E. Stiglitz in PDF and/or ePUB format, as well as other popular books in Volkswirtschaftslehre & Wirtschaftstheorie. We have over one million books available in our catalogue for you to explore.

Information

PART
I
HEALTH CARE REFORM
CHAPTER
1
The Health Care Reform Legislation: An Overview
Chapin White
Chapin White is a Senior Health Researcher at the Center for Studying Health System Change (HSC). He was an analyst at the Congressional Bud get Office (CBO) from 2004 through 2010 and was one of the lead analysts working on the scoring of the health care reform bill. The analysis and conclusions expressed in this chapter are the authorā€™s alone and should not be interpreted as those of the CBO or HSC.
THE AFFORDABLE CARE ACT (ACA) represents the most significant overhaul of our health care system since the establishment of Medicare and Medicaid. The ACA does two things: First, it fundamentally shifts the social contract in the United States. Starting in 2014, individuals will be required to have health insurance; in return, the federal government will significantly expand low-income health insurance subsidies. Second, it significantly rebalances the financing for Medicare by reducing the growth in outlays and increasing Medicare taxes paid by high earners.
This chapter provides non-specialists with a guide to the major provisions, their logic, and the federal budgetary implications. (All revenue and spending figures that follow refer to 10-year totals for FY 2010 to 2019 and are based on CBO and Joint Tax Committee estimates.)
MEDICARE
The ACA reduces Medicare outlays by roughly $400 billion. Two-thirds of this comes from reduced growth in the payment rates that medical providers receive in the traditional fee-for-service program (see Table 1.1). Most of the rest comes from reductions in premiums paid to privately managed care plans. The payment rate reductionsā€”roughly one percentage point a yearā€”apply broadly to most types of medical ser vices, except for physicians (who have no reductions) and home health care agencies (which face disproportionately large cuts).
On the revenue side, the ACA raises Medicare hospital insurance (HI) taxes by over $200 billion. Starting in 2013, earnings above a cutoff ($200,000 for singles; $250,000 for couples) will be subject to an additional 0.9 percent tax, on top of the current 2.9 percent. Also starting in 2013, high-earning families will pay a new 3.8 percent HI tax on net investment income (interest, dividends, rents, and taxable capital gains). The ACA also raises the premiums that high-income Medicare beneficiaries will pay for physician and prescription drug coverage and reduces federal subsidies to hospitals that disproportionately serve low-income patients (DSH). Also, deductibles and coinsurance in Medicare Part D prescription drug plans (the ā€œdonut holeā€) will shrink over the next decade, due to a combination of manufacturer discounts and additional federal financing.
The combination of reduced outlays and increased revenues substantially improves Medicareā€™s fiscal picture and pushes the Part A insolvency dateā€”the year in which the Medicare Trustees project that the HI trust fund will be exhaustedā€”from 2017 to 2029. The reduction in premiums paid to Medicare Advantage will likely lead those plans to raise premiums or cut benefits, which will cause some beneficiaries to shift out of those plans and back to the fee-for-service program.
TABLE 1.1
Summary of the Major Provisions in the ACA
Effect on Federal Deficit (2010ā€“19, $ billions)
Medicare Provisions
Reduced provider payment rates ā€“230
Reduced premiums to private plans ā€“140
Increased premiums for high-income beneficiaries ā€“40
Close ā€œdonut holeā€ 40
New HI tax on high earners ā€“210
Miscellaneous (DSH, IPAB, CMI, ACOs, bundling, etc.) ā€“50
Net, Medicare Provisions ā€“610
Coverage and Revenue Provisions
Medicaid expansion 430
Exchange credits 460
Small business credit 40
Tax on health insurers and manufacturers ā€“110
Penalties on firms and individuals ā€“70
Limit deductibility of health care expenses ā€“30
Nonhealth revenue provisions ā€“50
High-premium excise tax ā€“20
Reduce Medicaid Rx prices ā€“40
Miscellaneous (administrative simplification, high-risk pool, early retirees, etc.) ā€“30
Net, Coverage and Revenue Provisions 590
Note: This table excludes the off-budget effects of the ACA on the Social Security program and excludes the CLASS act and the education provisions in the ACA.
Rhetoric claiming that the ACA will accomplish more fundamental Medicare reform is generally overblown. For example, the new Independent Payment Advisory Board (IPAB) has been touted as the ACAā€™s ā€œmost important institutional change.ā€ The concept was to delegate to a body outside Congress the authority to make fiscally sound, but unpopular, changes to Medicare. But IPAB is highly constrained in its design. Its reforms are limited in nature (no rationing, no restricting benefits); in scope (hospitals and most other providers are off-limits until 2019); and in timing (IPAB can only make reforms if projected Medicare-spending growth exceeds a target growth rate). Crucially, IPABā€™s target growth rateā€”GDP per capita plus one percentage pointā€”is unsustainably high, which essentially ensures that IPAB will not solve Medicareā€™s long-term financing problem.
Three other Medicare provisions have also received outsized attention:
ā€¢ Center for Medicare and Medicaid Innovation (CMI). The ACA expands the executive branchā€™s authority to conduct ā€œdemonstrationsā€ testing alternative payment and delivery systems in Medicare and Medicaid. How the CMI will play out is highly uncertain. The CBO projected that it would have essentially no impact on spending.
ā€¢ Accountable care organizations (ACOs). The concept behind ACOs is to encourage medical providers to form integrated systems and to incentivize those systems to reduce utilization while meeting quality benchmarks. But under the ACA, provider participation is purely voluntary, and incentives are one-sided: bonuses are available for ACOs that come in below a spending target, but there is no penalty for overshooting. Some ACOs will likely end up earning windfall bonuses due to the natural variability in health spending. The CBO guessed that, on the whole, ACOs would very modestly reduce Medicare spending, but those windfalls could very easily end up increasing it instead.
ā€¢ Bundling. Paying medical providers for a broadly defined ā€œbundleā€ of ser vices (rather than by individual ser vice) holds great promise for reining in cost growth. The ACA includes a bundling provision but only creates a limited pi lot program for payments for hospital and post-acute care.
COVERAGE
The ACAā€™s core coverage goals were (1) to ensure that everyone, regardless of health status or income, has adequate access to health insurance and health care; and (2) to minimize disruptions to the current system. The ACAā€™s coverage provisions have four interdependent components: (1) subsidies for low-income individuals; (2) an individual mandate; (3) a prohibition on insurersā€™ denying coverage or varying premiums on the basis of health status; and (4) the definition of a minimum health insurance package. Without the subsidies, health care is unaffordable for those with low incomes. Without the mandate, healthier individuals opt out of the market, possibly leading to collapse. Without the limits on insurers, market pressures force them to charge higher premiums to individuals in poor health status or deny them coverage altogether. The defined minimum benefit package is necessary to determine whether individuals have satisfied the mandate and whether they have enrolled in coverage that is eligible for the new subsidies.
Subsidies. Medicaidā€”which provides health care coverage with no premiums and very low or no cost sharingā€”has historically only been available to children in very low-income families, and their parents. Starting in 2014, the ACA will expand eligibility to every person below 138 percent of the federal poverty level (FPL) including, most importantly, adults without young children. This expansion is, in my judgment, the largest single component of the ACA. It accounts for roughly half of gross coverage costs. By 2019, it will shift roughly 16 million people into Medicaid (a number nearly as large as the number of elderly persons who enrolled in Medicare when it was first launched). For the non-elderly and non-disabled, the ACA standardizes the income-counting rules used for determining Medicaid eligibility and eliminates asset tests. Additional provisions streamline and simplify enrollment in Medicaid.
Beginning in 2014, the ACA will offer a refundable tax credit for the purchase of health insurance through newly established health insurance markets (ā€œexchangesā€). These credits (discussed in the chapter in this book by Duggan and Kocher) account for the bulk of the remainder of gross coverage costs. The ACA also includes an employer tax credit that can offset up to half of employer contributions for health insurance, but only for very small firms with low-wage workers. This credit, compared to other aspects of the ACA, is small and has relatively little impact on coverage.
Individual mandate. Also beginning in 2014, the ACA will require almost everyone in the United States to enroll in health insurance. Once fully phased in, the penalty for not doing so will equal the greater of a flat dollar amount ($695 per uninsured adult) and 2.5 percent of family income. Groups exempt from the penalty include families with income below the income-tax-filing threshold; American Indians; and families for whom the cost of coverage would be unaffordable (defined as exceeding 8 percent of income) or would result in hardship (to be defined later). The IRS will monitor compliance and assess penalties through the tax system.
Limits on insurers. In most states, health insurers in the individual market have been permitted to choose whether to offer coverage based on an individualā€™s health history; exclude coverage for ā€œpreexistingā€ (i.e., already diagnosed) medical conditions; vary premiums on the basis of health status; and rescind coverage if the insurer uncovers ā€œmisstatementsā€ (whether intentional or not) on the enrolleeā€™s application. Under the ACA, starting in 2014, all four of those practices will be prohibited in the individual insurance market. The ACA also places new restrictions on insurers in the small-employer and large-employer markets, but those restrictions are generally not binding.
Minimum coverage. The ACA defines three rings of insurance coverage: The outermost ring consists of all coverage satisfying the individual mandate. (This includes everything we would deem ā€œrealā€ health insurance: Medicare counts, but not, say, vision only.) The second, smaller ring consists of all small-group and individual coverage. Starting in 2014, these plans must provide ā€œessential health benefits,ā€ which will include coverage of a broad set of ser vices (hospital, prescription drugs, etc.), and must choose a cost-sharing design that fits into one of five actuarial value tiers (ā€œplatinum,ā€ ā€œgold,ā€ etc.). The innermost ring consists of ā€œqualified health plansā€: plans offered through the new exchanges and potentially eligible for exchange credits. These plans must be certified by the exchanges as meeting additional criteria relating to plan quality, marketing, and value.
REVENUES
To offset the cost of its subsidies, the ACA raises federal revenues from various sources, mostly within the health care system. These revenues include: broad-based taxes on health insurers and makers of brand-name prescription drugs and medical devices; penalties on large employers that do not offer affordable health coverage and on uninsured individuals; limits on the deductibility of medical expenses for individuals and firms; and some miscellaneous nonhealth revenue provisions (e.g., an excise tax on indoor tanning). The ACA also includes several provisions that reduce federal outlays and thereby offset some of the coverage costs, such as a reduction in the prices that Medicaid will pay for prescription drugs.
MARKETS
Several major components of the ACA attempt to correct perceived market distortions, create new markets, or improve the functioning of existing markets. Besides exchanges, discussed in the chapter by Duggan and Kocher, these changes include:
ā€¢ Limiting the tax subsidy for employer-sponsored coverage. The tax treatment of employer-sponsored health benefitsā€”that is, deductibility for the employer and exclusion from taxable income for the employeeā€”has long drawn fire from economists, most notably Martin Feldstein, for putting upward pressure on health care costs. The ACA takes a small step in the direction of limiting that tax subsidy. Beginning in 2018, insurers and self-insured employers will be subject to an excise tax on employer-sponsored health benefits in excess of a ceiling. The ceiling will be at least $10,200 for single plans and $27,500 for family plans in 2018ā€”higher if premiums grow faster than expected, if an employerā€™s workforce is unusually old, or if the enrollee is a retiree or a worker in a high-risk profession. The ceiling, which is indexed to the Consumer Price Index-All Urban Consumers (CPI-U), will likely grow more slowly than premiums, which means that its impact is projected to grow gradually.
ā€¢ A new long-term-care insurance product. The private market for long-term-care insurance has never really gotten off the ground due, at least in part, to the inherent instability in private insurance contracts spanning many years or decades. The ACA establishes the Community Living Assistance Ser vices and Supports (CLASS) program, which was designed to be a voluntary, community-rated long-term-care insurance product administered by the federal government and fully funded by enrollee premiums. (In late 2011, the Administration determined that the CLASS program could not be implemented in a financially sustainable way, and the program has been discontinued.)
ā€¢ Administrative simplification. The ACA broadens the scope of federal regulations governing interactions among health insurers and providers (e.g., submission of claims for payment, eligibility verification). The CBO judged that the resulting reduction in premiums would be ā€œmodestā€ in percentage terms, but the base over which those savings accrueā€”almost the whole of health spending in the United Statesā€”is enormous.
ā€¢ Minimum loss ratios (MLRs). The ACA requires, as of 2011, that health insurers spend at least a minimum percentage of their premium revenues on medical claims (i.e., losses) or quality-improvement activities. That minimum...

Table of contents

  1. CoverĀ 
  2. Half title
  3. Title
  4. Copyright
  5. ContentsĀ 
  6. Part I: Health Care Reform
  7. Part II: Financial Market Regulatory Reform
  8. Part III: Financial Crisis and Bailouts
  9. Part IV: Innovations in Policy and Business
  10. Index